Skip to main content

Full text of "Brannan, Secretary of Agriculture v. Stark, 185 F.2d 871 (D.C. Cir. 1950)"

See other formats


United States Court of Appeals 

for the 

District of Columbia Circuit 



TRANSCRIPT OF 
RECORD 








7Wr» 



1 > a ft A :h 





































INDEX 


PAGE 


Jurisdictional Statement . 1 

Statutes and Orders Involved- 2 

Statement of the Case; the Intervenor’s Charge of 

Champerty and Maintenance . 6 

Statement of Points .. 11 

Outline of Argument . 12 

Point I 


The Present Suit Was Instigated and Carried on 
by the Large Dairies. Plaintiffs Do Not Repre- 
sent Producers As a Class But Handlers and the 
Court Below Should Have Denied Relief. 14 

Point II 

Congress Has Authorized the Secretary of Agri¬ 
culture, Upon Proper Findings, Based on Sub¬ 
stantial Evidence Received at Hearings to Pro¬ 
vide for Payments to Producer-owned and Con¬ 
trolled Co-operative Associations for Services 
Rendered to Effectuate the Purposes of the Act 
and of a Marketing Order Issued Thereunder. 

The District Court Erred in Its Contrary Holding 19 

Point HI 

The Court Below Erroneously Concluded That 
the Secretary Exceeded His Statutory Authority 
in Inserting in the Order the Provision for Deduc¬ 
tions for Payment to Co-operative Associations_ 28 

Point IV 

The Secretary’s Order Was an Administrative 
Interpretation of His Authority Which Is En- 

l*Jl 1 l 1 TTT • V l A i 


titled to Great Weight. 34 

Point V 

Subsequent Legislative History Supports the 
Validity of the Co-operative Payment Provision 
Involved Here . 36 


Appendix I Extract from Bulletin DM-6, Dept, of 

Agriculture—Payments Out of Pool.... 43 












11 


INDEX (Continued) 


PAGE 

Appendix II Extract from Compilation, Dept, of 

Agriculture . 44 

Appendix III Statement of E. W. Gaumnitz . 46 

Appendix IV Extract from Report of Committee on 

Agriculture . 48 

Table of Cases 

PAGE 

Amer. Power & Light Co. v. Sec., 329 U. S. 90, 112 .... 23 

Armour Co. v. Wantock, 323 U. S. 126, 129 . 20 

Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Anderson, 157 F. 2d 87. 31 

Baldwin v. Seelig, 294 U. S. 511 .. 29 

Bickford’s Inc. v. Federal Reserve Bank, 5 Fed. Sup. 

875, 877 .-. 18 

Billings v. Truesdell, 321 U. S. 542, 552 . 35 

Birnbaum v. U. S., 107 F. 2d 885, 887 - 40 

Burford v. Sun Oil Co., 319 U. S. 315, 318-19. 16 

Burns v. Scott, 117 U. S. 528, 591 . 15 

Caha v. U. S., 152 U. S. 211, 221_ 28, 34 

Clark v. Chase Natl. Bank, 45 Fed. Sup. 820, 823 _ 17,18 

Cudahy Packing Co. v. Holland, 315 U. S. 357, 366 _ 27 

Dickey v. Raisin Proration Zone 24 Cal. 2d 796 . 20 

Dunwoody v. U. S., 22 Ct. Cl. 269, 288 . 20 

Fleming v. Mohawk Co., 331 U. S. Ill, 116. 35 

Frank Bros. v. NLRB, 321 U. S. 702, 704 . 21 

Fox v. Standard Oil Co., 294 U. S. 87, 96 .. 27 

Gemsco v. Walling, 324 U. S. 244, 255 _ 21, 23, 30, 35 

General Investment Co. v. Bethlehem Steel Co., 248 
Fed. 303 ... 20 






















INDEX (Continued) 


PAGE 

Ginsberg & Sons v. Popkin, 285 U. S. 244 - 24 

Gray v. Powell, 314 U. S. 402, 411- 23, 35 

Greathouse v. Dern, 289 U. S. 352 --- 16 

Great Northern Ry. v. U. S., 315 U. S. 262, 272 — 24, 36 

Green Valley v. U. S., 108 F. 2d 342 - 31 

Harrison v. Northern Trust Co., 317 U. S. 476, 479 — 27 

Heiskell v. Mozie, 65 App. D. Ci 255, 257, 82 Fed. 2d 
861, 863 ____ 14 

Hoffman v. Palmer, 129 F. 2d 976, 985 - 40 

H. B. Hood & Sons v. DuMond, 69 S. Ct. 657, 666 — 28 

Illinois Gas Co. v. Central Illinois Co., 314 U. S. 498 .. 35 

Jamison Coal Co. v. Goltra, 143 F. 2d 889, 895 - 15 

Johnson v. Van Wyck, 4 App. D. C. 294, 323-4 -- 15 

Kalamazoo Auto Sales Co. v. Travelers Ins. Co., 222 
Michigan 74, 198 .-. 22 

Liberty Warehouse v. Burley Co-operative, 276 U. S. 

71, 92-93 ..15, 27 

Lichter v. U. S., 334 U. S. 742, 785.21, 24 

Lilly v. Grand Trunk Western Ry., 317 U. S. 481, 

488 ...28, 34 

Lord v. Veazie, 8 How. 251_ 18 

Matter of Cregan, 275 N. T. 337 . 40 

Meeker v. Straat, 38 Mo. A. 239, 243. 18 

Merchants Exchange v. Mo., 248 U. S. 365, 366 . 40 

Metropolitan R. Co. v. Moore, 121 U. S. 558, 572 . 40 

Middleton v. Parker, 3 App. D. C. 149, 160 .. 20 

Morton Salt Co. v. Suppiger, 314 U. S. 488, 492 _ 16 

Nebbia v. New York, 291 U. S. 500 ........ 29 

Nichols & Co. v. Sec. of Agriculture, 131 F. 2d 651, 658 20 



























IV 


INDEX (Continued) 


page 

NLRB v. Hearst Publications, 322 U. S. Ill, 131. 21 

NLRB v. Lorillard Co., 314 U. S. 512.- 22 

Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341, 354 . 40 

Phelps Dodge v. NLRB, 313 U. S. 177. 21 

Porter v. Murray, 156 F. 2d 781, 785 . 39 

Securities & Exchange Comm. v. Joiner L. Corp., 320 
U. S. 344, 357 . 24 

Sioux Tribe v. U. S., 316 U. S. 317, 329 . 39 

Southern S. S. Co. v. NLRB, 315 U. S. 31, 46. 21 

Stark v. Wickard, 321 IT. S. 288.12,14,18, 31 

Swayne & Hoyt v. U. S., 300 U. S. 297, 302 . 33 

Thompson v. Consolidated Gas Co., 300 U. S. 55, 69..„ 23 

Thorsch v. Miller, 5 F. 2d 118, 121. 28 

Tigner v. Texas, 310 U. S. 141, 145 . 27 

U. S. v. Amer. Truck Assoc., 310 U. S. 534, 542 . 24 

U. S. v. Bush &• Co., 310 U. S. 317. 22 

U. S. v. C. I. O., 325 U. S. 106,112. 24 

U. S. v. Denver & Rio Grande R., 150 U. S. 1. 20 

U. S. v. Kelly, 55 Fed. 2d 67, 70 . 23 

F. S. v. Rock Roval, 307 U. S. 533, 575 

. 19, 21, 27, 29, 34, 36, 37 

U. S. v. United Machinery Co., 64 Fed. 138. 27 

U. S. v. Von Clemm, 136 F. 2d 969, 970 . 23 

Virginia Electric Co. v. NLRB, 319 U. S. 533, 539 . 35 

Ward v. Alsup, 100 Tenn. 619, 739 . 18 

Warehime v. Varney, 147 F. 2d 238 . 22 

White v. Winchester C. C., 315 U. S. 32, 41. 35 

Yakus v. U. S., 321 U. S. 414, 427 . 21 






























INDEX (Continued) 


v 


PAGE 

Statutes Involved 

Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, 7 
USC 601 

Section 8c(l), issuance by Secretary. 12 

Section 8c(5) Milk and Its Products; Terms and 
Conditions of Orders. 2, 13, 24, 25, 29-34 

Section 608c(7) Terms Common to All Orders 
.2, 13, 19, 24, 25 

Boston Marketing Order, 12 F. R. 4921 7 CFR 1947 

Supp. 3 

Section 904.0 Findings. 3 

Section 904.9 Payments to Cooperative Associa¬ 
tions . 4 

Section 904.9 Further Provisions. 4 

Amendment of August 1, 1947 to Section 
904.10(b)(1) . 5 

Capper-Volstead Act, 7 U. S. C. 291.15, 25 

Rules of Civil Procedure, Rule 23a . 17 

NLRB Act, Tit. 29 U. S. C. 20 

Commodity Exchange Act, 7 U. S. C. 20 

Bituminous Coal Conservation Act, 15 U. S. C. 21 

Tobacco Inspection Act, 7 U. S. C. 21 

Agricultural Adjustment Act, 7 U. S. C. 21 

Emergency Price Control Act, 50 U. S. C. 21 

Fair Labor Standards Act, 29 U. S. C. 21 

Miscellaneous 

Moore’s Fed. Practice, 3419. 18 

Words and Phrases, Yol. 20, Page 423 . 20 

Gaumnitz, Statement . 37 



























In The 


Ittitrii $tat?s (Eourt of A 


MU 


F T 



Foe the District of Columbia Circuit 


Nos. 10,365 and 10,366 


Charles F. Brannan, Secretary of Agriculture, 

Appellant, 


and 


Dairymen’s League Co-operative Association, Inc., 

Intervenor- Appellant, 
v. 

Delbert 0. Stark, et al, 

Appellees. 


On Appeal From the Judgment of the United States 
District Court for the District of Columbia 


BRIEF FOR INTERVENOR-APPELLANT 
DAIRYMEN’S LEAGUE CO-OPERATIVE 
ASSOCIATION, INC. 


JURISDICTIONAL STATEMENT 

The Dairymen’s League Cooperative Association Inc. 
intervened as a party defendant in the Court below. It 
filed its notice of appeal June 22, 1949, (App. 157). Its 
appeal was, by order of this Court, consolidated for hear¬ 
ing with No. 10365. Jurisdiction of this Court is in¬ 
voked under Title 28, U. S. Code Section 1291 and 1294. 







2 


STATUTES AND ORDERS INVOLVED 

The following are relevant sections of the Agricultural 
Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (7 U. S. C. 601 et seq .): 
§608c. Orders Regulating Handling of Commodity. 

(1) Issuance by Secretary. 

Sec. Sc (1) The Secretary of Agriculture shall, subject 
to the provisions of this section, issue, and from time to 
time amend, orders applicable to processors, associations 
of producers, and others engaged in the handling of any 
agricultural commodity or product thereof specified in 
subsection (2) of this section. Such orders shall regu¬ 
late, in the manner hereinafter in this section provided, 
only such handling of such agricultural commodity, or 
product thereof, as is in the current of interstate or for¬ 
eign commerce, or which directly burdens, obstructs, or 
affects, interstate or foreign commerce in such commodity 
or product thereof. 

(5) Milk and Its Products; Terms and Conditions of 
Orders. 

(5) In the case of milk and its products, orders issued 
pursuant to this section shall contain one or more of the 
following terms and conditions, and (except as provided 
in subsection (7) no others: 

(The remainder of Sec. (5) deals with the classifica¬ 
tion and pricing of milk.) 

Sec. 608c(7) 7 erms Common to All Orders. 

(7) In the case of the agricultural commodities and the 
products thereof specified in subsection (2) orders shall 
contain one or more of the following terms and conditions: 

(D) Incidental to, and not inconsistent with, the terms 
and conditions specified in subsections (5), (6), and (7) 



3 


and necessary to effectuate the other provisions of such 
order. 

The following are relevant sections of the Boston milk 
marketing order, as amended (12 F. R. 4921, 7 CFR, 1947 
Supp., 904.0 et seq .): 

The Order set out the findings of the Secretary as fol¬ 
lows : 

Section 904.0. Findings. The Secretary finds, upon 
the evidence introduced at the last above-mentioned 
hearings, said findings being in addition to the findings 
made upon the evidence introduced at the original 
hearings on said order, and on amendments to said 
order, and being in addition to the other findings 
and determinations made prior to or at the time of 
the original issuance of said order, and of amendments 
thereto (which findings are hereby ratified and affirmed 
save only as such findings are in conflict with the find¬ 
ings hereinafter set forth): 

1. That the prices calculated to give milk produced 
for sale in said marketing area a purchasing power 
equivalent to the purchasing power of such milk, as 
determined pursuant to section 2 and 8(e) of said 
act, are not reasonable in view of the price of feeds, 
the available supplies of fees, and other economic 
conditions which affect the market supply and demand 
for such milk, and that the minimum prices fixed in 
this order, as amended, are such prices as will reflect 
the aforesaid factors, insure a sufficient quantity of 
pure and wholesome milk, and be in the public in¬ 
terest; * * • 

3. That the provisions relating to the payments out 
of the equalization pool to cooperative associations 
performing certain marketing services are incidental 
to, not inconsistent with, the other provisions of the 
order, as amended, and necessary to effectuate the 
other provisions of the order, as amended. 

4. That all the remaining provisions of the order, 
as amended, are necessary to effectuate the other pro¬ 
visions of the order, as amended; 

That the issuance of the order, as amended, and all 
of its terms and conditions will tend to effectuate the 
declared policy of the act. 


4 


Sec. 904J). Payments to cooperative associations. 
(a) Eligibility of cooperative associations. Upon ap¬ 
plication to the Secretary any cooperative association 
duly organized under the laws of any State which he 
determines, after appropriate inquiry or investigation, 
to be conforming to the provisions of such laws and 
of the Capper-Volstead Act, as amended, as to char¬ 
acter of organization, voting requirements, dividend 
payments dealing in products of non-members; to be 
operating as a responsible producer-controlled mar¬ 
keting association exercising full authority in the sale 
of the milk of its members; to be systematically check¬ 
ing the weights and tests of milk delivered by its 
members to plants other than those which may be 
operated by itself; to guarantee payments to its pro¬ 
ducers; to be maintaining, either individually or in 
collaboration with other qualified cooperative asso¬ 
ciations, a competent staff for dealing with market¬ 
ing problems and providing information to its mem¬ 
bers with whom close "working relationships are con¬ 
stantly maintained; to be collaborating with other sim¬ 
ilar associations in activities incident to the main¬ 
tenance and strengthening of collective bargaining by 
producers and the operation of a plant of uniform 
pricing of milk to handlers; and to be complying with 
all provisions of this order applicable to such coopera¬ 
tive association, shall be entitled to receive payments 
in the amount and under the conditions herein speci¬ 
fied from the date of qualification, as fixed by the 
Secretary, until it has been found by the Secretary 
after notice and opportunity for a hearing, that it has 
failed to continue to meet any condition or to maintain 
and exercise the authority or to perform any of the 
functions required by this section for the receipt or 
use of such payments. 

Section 9043 of the Order further provides: 

(1) Any such cooperative association shall receive 
an amount computed at not more than the rate of 1 y 2 
cents per hundred-weight of milk marketed by it on 
behalf of its members in conformity with the provi¬ 
sion of this order, the value of which is determined 
pursuant to Sec. 904.7(a), and with respect to which 
a handler has made payments as required by Sec. 



5 


904.8(b)(3) and Sec. 904.10; Provided, That the 
amount paid shall not exceed the amount which han¬ 
dlers are obligated to deduct from payments to mem¬ 
bers under subsection (e) hereof and are not used in 
paying patronage dividends or other payments to 
members with respect to milk delivered except in ful¬ 
filling the guarantee of payments to producers; and 
that in cases where two or more associations partici¬ 
pate in the marketing of the same milk, payment 
under this paragraph shall be available only to the 
association which the individual producer has made 
his exclusive agent in the marketing of such milk. 

(2) Any such cooperative association shall receive 
an amount computed at the rate of 5 cents per hun¬ 
dred-weight on Class I milk received from producers 
at a plant operated under the exclusive control of 
member producers, which is sold to proprietary han¬ 
dlers. This amount shall not be received on milk 
sold to stores, to handlers, in which the cooperative 
has any ownership, or to a handler with which the 
cooperative has such sales arrangements that its milk 
not sold as Class I milk to such handler is not avail¬ 
able for sale as Class I milk to other handlers. 

Amendment dated August 1, 1947, to Section 
904.10, as amended, August 1,1941, 7 CFR, 1947 Supp. 
904.10: 

Sec. 904.10(b)(1) Each qualified association shall 
be entitled to payment at the rate of 1 cent per hun¬ 
dred weight on the milk which its producer members 
deliver to the plant of a handler other than a qualified 
association; except on milk delivered by a producer 
who is also a member of another qualified association, 
and on milk delivered to a handler who fails to make 
applicable payments pursuant to §904.9 (b) (2) and 
§904.11 within 10 days after the end of the month in 
which he is required to do so. If the handler is re¬ 
quired by paragraph (e) of this section to make de¬ 
ductions from members of the association at a rate 
lower than 1 cent per hundred weight, the payment 
pursuant to this subparagraph shall be at such lower 
rate. 

(1) Each qualified association shall be entitled to 
payment at the rate of 2 cents per hundred weight 
on milk received from producers at a plant operated 
by that association. 



6 


STATEMENT OF THE CASE 

The Dairymen’s League Cooperative Association, Inc., 
which has intervened as a party defendant with the per¬ 
mission of the Court is a cooperative corporation which 
acts as the marketing agent for many thousands of pro¬ 
ducers of milk in Massachusetts, New York, Vermont, 
Connecticut, Pennsylvania and New Jersey. (App. 55) 

The intervenor adopts the statement of the case con¬ 
tained in appellant’s brief. It should be emphasized that 
appellees are non-members of any cooperative. However, 
under the Secretary’s milk orders, non-member producers 
receive the same price for their milk and thus reap 
the advantages of the intervenor’s activities. 


THE INTERVENOR’S CHARGE OF CHAMPERTY 
AND MAINTENANCE: 

The intervenor submitted the following additional de¬ 
fense : 

The intervenor, by leave of the Court, amended its an¬ 
swer, Paragraph 13, by alleging the following: 

“(13) Further answering the complaint, as 
amended, this defendant alleges, upon information and 
belief, that the plaintiffs herein are merely nominal 
parties and that this action in reality has been brought 
and is being prosecuted by and for the benefit of 
certain handlers of milk in the Greater Boston milk 
marketing area who have no legal standing to attack 
the validity of the so-called ‘co-operative payment 
provisions’ contained in Section 904.9 of Order No. 4 
regulating the handling of milk in the Greater Boston 
milk marketing area; that the attorneys for the plain¬ 
tiffs were chosen and paid by said handlers and all 
expenses of this action have been paid by said han¬ 
dlers; that said handlers are using the names of the 
plaintiffs herein as a subterfuge because of their legal 
incapacity to maintain a cause of action.” (App. 
141,466-467) 





7 


As to the above defense, the evidence shows that plain¬ 
tiffs below, non-members of any cooperative, were five 
small producers of milk in the Boston area who sold their 
product either to the Whiting Milk Company or H. P. Hood 
and Sons, Inc., the two largest handlers of milk in the 
Boston marketing area. (App. 255, 278, 300, 331, 265) 
Appellees have never paid a dollar to defray attorneys 
fees or expenses of the present litigation. (App. 262, 309, 
348) Mr. Polikoff, plaintiffs original attorney, charged 
$5,112.55 which was paid in its entirety by Hood, Whiting 
and three other major handlers. (App. 450). Their later 
representative, Ropes, Gray, Best, Coolidge and Rugg 
charged, up to February 28, 1948, $17,751.74, prior to 
the trial, which was paid by the Hood Dairy. (App. 450) 
This firm is the regularly retained attorneys for the Hood 
Dairy (App. 414, 433). 

Plaintiff Stratton has died since the institution of the 
suit (App. 350); plaintiff Stebbins has since joined a 
qualified cooperative from which he receives benefits. 
(App. 281). Plaintiffs have sued for themselves and for 
the benefit of all other persons similarly situated. (R. 
2). The answer of defendant (App. 48) traversed these 
allegations, which were not admitted by the Intervenor. 
(App. 52, amended answer. App. 141, 466-7). Although 
the complaint alleges irreparable damage to plaintiffs 
(Comp. 14, 15, App. 6), the reasons for their objections 
to the deduction do not include financial loss as the result 
of the deduction in question but are ideologic in character. 
(App. 266-7). Thus Stark contended that the services ren¬ 
dered by the cooperatives did not justify them in asking 
non-members to chip in and pay their expenses, (App. 332- 
332, 355); that if the present deduction was valid, money 
could be taken from the pool for a Christmas Club or 
Community Welfare. (App. 332). Denton stated he did 
not believe in equalization and saw no reason to divide 
with his neighbors. (App. 329, 335-6). Walsh stated that 
the producers wanted to go into his pay check and take 


8 


money out (App. 276-277) and anyhow he objected to the 
equalization pool generally. (App. 275,276). 

A reading of the depositions of the plaintiffs (App. 
254-363) shows that none of them had much understanding 
of the basis of the Secretary's finding in the Order as 
to the services the cooperatives render to promote or¬ 
derly marketing and to maintain and enhance prices to 
producers. (See App. 283,336,354-5). 

The suit was instituted mainly through the activities 
of Stark. Stark and Denton were present at producers’ 
relationship meetings sponsored by the Whiting Dairy at 
which Whiting officials stated why the Whiting Dairy was 
opposed to the cooperatives deduction in principal but 
that it was up to the producers to initiate any move. The 
company would render any assistance it could. (App. 
331). A possible law* suit was discussed and the first at¬ 
torney to enter the case, a New York lawyer named 
Polikoff, was suggested to Stark by the president of Whit¬ 
ing who later took Stark and Denton to call on the lawyer 
in a Boston Hotel. (App. 322,337-9). 

No understanding was had with the lawyer as to the 
payment of his fees or court costs or the amount thereof. 
(App. 261, 339-340). The plaintiffs never had any idea 
of what the case might cost nor had they ever received 
any bill. (App. 262, 272-274, 280, 307, 309, 313, 348). 
However, they stated they expected to contribute some¬ 
thing themselves and later arranged with certain other 
Whiting producers that one cent per hundredweight of 
their milk should be deducted from their pay checks. 
(App. 308). This was done for a short period in 1941, 
the total amount collected being around $400 which is 
still being held by Whiting. (App. 308, 309, 368). Stark 
expected Whiting to contribute and Whiting was willing 
to do this. (App. 348,361,368). 

Stebbins and Walsh were Hood Dairy producers. (App. 
255). Stark asked the former to go along to stop the de- 








9 


duction. (App. 278-9). Stebbins has since joined a co¬ 
operative. (App. 281). 

Walsh was persuaded to enter the case by a field repre¬ 
sentative of the Hood Dairy who was looking for a New 
York producer to get into the case. (App. 260). Walsh 
expected to pay his share, (App. 261) although he had 
no idea what it would be, (App. 262, 272-274) and could 
not afford much. (R. 274). He understood the Hood 
Dairy would help out. (App. 274). 

Only Stark recalled meeting the first attorney. (App. 
280, 338). Plaintiffs except Stark (App. 345) never heard 
of the attorney who succeeded him, although the new at¬ 
torney received payments for legal services in 1941. 
Stark heard nothing about the case from the time it went 
to the Supreme Court in 1944 until the new attorney vis¬ 
ited him in 1948. (App. 361). At that time Stark him¬ 
self was out of the milk business as he had sold his herd 
the previous April and in 1948 was employed in a grain 
store. (App. 352). Stark re-entered the milk market in 
September, 1948, with five cows. (App. 352). 

As of the end of 1945, Stark’s deductions for co-opera¬ 
tive payments amounted to around $100. (App. 357). 
Walsh’s deductions amounted to around six cents a day 
(App. 267). Stebbins interest in the deduction for 1946, 
1947 and 1948 at tvro cents a day w*ould amount to around 
$210.00. (App. 287). Denton, from 1941 to 1948, had 
deductions at stake of around $242. (App. 326). The 
1947 amendment to Sec. 904 reduced the deduction to 1 % 
cents a hundredweight. (This Brief p. 4). Prior to 
the 1947 amendment the total deduction paid the coopera¬ 
tive was around $15,575.31 a month. (App. 89). 

The principal handlers, particularly Hood, the largest 
milk dealer in New England, had been opposed to the co¬ 
operative deduction on the ground that it gave coopera¬ 
tives a competitive advantage over the handlers. (App. 






10 


75, 35S, 369, 370, 395, 406, 428, 458). They admitted it 
did not affect their cost of product. (App. 367). These 
handlers attempted to defeat the deduction in public hear¬ 
ings (App. 371-2; 442 Public Hearing Record 745-758, 
S24-S32, 789-S00). The president of the Hood Dairy stated 
that his company was opposed to the cooperative deduc¬ 
tions from the pool and admitted his company had been 
requested to contribute something. He stated that the 
firm of Ropes, Gray, Best, Coolidge and Rugg, of record 
as representing plaintiffs, were attorneys for his company 
and that his company would like to see the cooperative 
payment provision removed from the Order. (App. 428, 
433,445, 449-450). 

The Hood Dairy stated that the charges of the first at¬ 
torney for plaintiffs, Mr. Polikoff, for legal services from 
1941 through July, 1943, amounted to $5,112.55, one-half 
of which was paid by the Hood Dairy. (App. 450). The 
charges of the Ropes, Gray, Best, Coolidge and Rugg firm 
for the period from 1941 through February, 1948, for 
legal services and disbursements amounted to $17,751.74, 
which bill the Hood Dairy paid. (App. 450). Mr. Mer¬ 
rill, Accounting Chief of Hood’s Legal Division, stated 
he believed Hood had been reimbursed in part for these 
charges by other handlers. (App. 450). 

This is alleged to be a class suit, plaintiffs alleging 
that they represent six-thousand non-member producers 
similarly situated. (App. 2). However, plaintiffs admitted 
all producers shipping to Hood and Whiting were not 
opposed to the cooperative deductions. (App. 256, 274). 
Whiting’s representative agreed with them, (App. 370- 
371), also plaintiff Walsh. (App. 256). In 1941 there 
were 15,603 producers in the Boston area, 10,801 being 
members of cooperatives and 4,802 being non-members. 
(App. 296). Of the non-members, 843 voted in the refer¬ 
endum, of which number only 42 voted against the de¬ 
duction. (App. 296). 




11 


The cooperative deductions affect every producer in the 
market regardless of whether he is a member or non¬ 
member of a cooperative. 

The New York market has had an Order with similar 
provisions since 1938 and Cincinnati and Dayton-Spring- 
field have similar Orders. (App. 389, 410, 416, 3 F. R. 
1943; 7 F. R. 9503; 10 F. R. 6162.) 

STATEMENT OF POINTS 

I 

The present suit is champertous, having been instigated 
and maintained by handlers, large dairies unable to sue 
in their own right. This fact bears (a) upon whether 
plaintiffs represent the class for which they purport to 
sue (b) whether a court of equity should strike down an 
important part of a governmental regulatory plan for 
the benefit of undisclosed principals. (See paragraph 13, 
Intervenor’s Amended Answer, App. 141, 466-467). 

n 

The deduction, i.e. sums paid to cooperatives for mar¬ 
ket-wide services, was incidental to and not inconsistent 
with the terms and conditions specified in Section 608c 
(5), (6), (7) of the Act and, as found by the Secretary, 
was necessary to effectuate the other provisions of his 
Order. 

i 

m 

Section 608c (7) of the Agricultural Marketing Agree¬ 
ment Act of 1937, as amended, (U. S. C. 601 et seq.) au¬ 
thorizes the deduction. 

IV 

The Secretary’s Order was an administrative determi¬ 
nation of his powers and a construction of the Act en¬ 
titled to great weight. 


12 


V 

Subsequent legislative history supports the validity of 
the deduction. 


OUTLINE OF ARGUMENT 
I 

The plaintiffs, non-members of any cooperative, purport 
to bring suit “for themselves and for the benefit of all 
other persons similarly situated.” (App. 2). The inter- 
venor, by amendment to paragraph 13 of its Answer, 
(App. 141) contended that plaintiffs were merely nominal 
parties and that in reality the suit was brought and was 
being prosecuted for certain large dairies, handlers of 
milk in the Boston market who under Stark v. Wickard 
321 TJ. S. 288 had no legal standing to attack the coopera¬ 
tive payment provision of the Order; that the attorneys 
for plaintiffs were chosen and paid by these handlers, 
who used the names of plaintiffs as a subterfuge because 
of their own legal incapacity to maintain the suit. The 
evidence shows that the first suggestion of a law suit came 
from the Whiting Dairy who procured the first attorney 
for plaintiffs, whose fee of $5,112.55 was entirely paid by 
Hood, Whiting and three other major handlers. Plaintiffs 
later representative, Ropes, Gray, Best, Coolidge and 
Rugg had been paid, up to February 28, 1948, $17,751.74. 
Plaintiffs have paid absolutely nothing by way of fees or 
expenses. 

The intervenor-appellant claims that the suit is thus 
champertous in character. Even assuming champerty or 
maintenance of a suitor does not destroy his cause of 
action as such , the fact should be considered by the Court 
(a) in respect of whether the suit is a true class suit (b) 
in respect of whether a court of equity should under these 
circumstances attempt to sustain a so-called private right 
of a non-member producer at the expense of a large num- 




13 


ber of member and non-member producers who are not 
before the Court. If the suit is not in truth a class suit 
then, even if the Court below was right, its judgment 
would, at most, be limited to these particular plaintiffs. 

n 

Congress has authorized the Secretary of Agriculture, 
upon proper findings, based on substantial evidence re¬ 
ceived at hearings, to provide for payments to producer- 
owned and controlled cooperative associations for services 
rendered to effectuate the purposes of the Act and of a 
marketing Order issued thereunder. The District Court 
erred in its contrary holding. The deduction is inciden¬ 
tal to, and not inconsistent with, the terms and conditions 
specified in Section 608c(5), (6), (7) and is necessary to 
effectuate the other provisions of the Order. “ Necessary ? ’ 
does not mean “indispensable, essential or vital.” The 
Court below was in error in construing “incidental” and 
“necessary’’ in a purely abstract manner and apart from 
the object of the provision. Further, the Court below 
ignored the specific findings of fact by the Secretary that 
such provision was incidental and necessary. 

m 

The Court below was in error in holding that the Statute 
did not expressly authorize such deductions. Section 
608c(5) in providing that milk orders “shall contain one 
or more of the following terms and conditions . . . and 
no others ’ ’ was qualified by the provisions of Section 608c 
(7) dealing with “Terms Common to All Orders,” Sub¬ 
section (D) of which authorizes provisions “incidental to 
. . . and necessary to effectuate the other provisions of 
such order.” 

IV 

The Secretary’s Order was an administrative interpreta¬ 
tion of his authority which is entitled to great weight ir- 



14 


respective of the length of time his ruling has been in ef¬ 
fect. Such a provision was inserted into the New York 
Order in 1937, in the Boston Order in 1941, in the Cincin¬ 
nati Order in 1944 and in the Dayton-Springfield Order in 
1945. Lapse of time is not the true test but expert knowl¬ 
edge of the problems involved. 

V 

Subsequent legislative history supports the validity of 
the cooperative payment provision. The Gillette bill in 
1940 shows a conclusive Congressional ratification of the 
provision. 

Point I 

The Present Suit Was Instigated and Carried On By the 
Large Dairies. Plaintiffs Do Not Represent Produ¬ 
cers As a Class But Handlers and the Court Below 
Should Have Denied Relief. 

As the present suit asks for equitable relief, this Court 
can “look through the shadow to the substance” (Heiskell 
v. Mozie, 65 App. D. C. 255, 257; 82 F. (2) 861, 863) as to 
the real party in interest. We think it fairly appears 
from the recital of facts herein (this brief pp. 6-11), 
that the present suit was instigated, or at least promoted, 
by the Hood and Whiting dairies, who under Stark v. 
Wickard, 321 U. S. 288, have no standing to sue in their 
own right. Plaintiffs’ attorneys, who are also attorneys 
for the Hood dairy (App. 414, 433), the largest dis¬ 
tributor in New England (App. 255, 265, 300, 331), ad¬ 
mitted below in their brief on the Motion to Dismiss, that 
the Hood and Whiting dairies are pecuniarily interested 
in the result of the present case and the record here shows 
this. (App. 331, 35S, 369-370, 395, 406, 428, 458). The 
record shows they have already paid one attorney $5,112.55 
and the Ropes, Gray firm $17,751.74 to carry it on. 
(App. 450) As against this, Plaintiffs have so far paid 
not a single dollar. (App. 262, 272-274, 280, 307, 309, 313, 


15 


348) Hood and Whiting’s interest is understandable: cut¬ 
ting off the co-operative’s funds will destroy its sinews 
of war, restrict its functions and services and by causing 
direct and higher contributions from members, cause irri¬ 
tation and friction, with ultimate demoralization as the 
end-result. Yet Congressional policy is strongly in favor 
of co-operatives. (Capper-Volstead Act, 7 U. S. C. 291; 
Liberty Warehouse v. Burley Co-operative, 276 U. S. 71, 
92-93). (See App. 85-87) But in addition to these in¬ 
admissible objectives, which we think peep through the 
present record, the large dairies have the claim that the 
“deduct” gives the co-operatives a competitive advantage. 
(App. 458) So there is plenty of reason why the large 
dairies are promoting and maintaining the present litiga¬ 
tion. 

We think this Court can take this factor into consider¬ 
ation. Even assuming that under the present state of the 
law champerty or maintenance of a suitor does not destroy 
his cause of action as such, (Burns v. Scott, 117 U. S. 582, 
591; Jamison Coal Co. v. Goltra, 143 F. (2) 889, 895; John¬ 
son v. Van Wyck, 4 App. D. C. 294, 323-4), still, as the 
present suit in asking equitable relief must appeal to the 
conscience of the Court, the fact that Plaintiffs are act¬ 
ing for another’s prime benefit and not for their own, and 
that the result of granting them relief will be mischief 
and not the public benefit, should have been considered by 
the Court in deciding their case. After all, Plaintiffs are 
asking no mean judicial action: for the few hundred dol¬ 
lars (See Statement of Facts, present Brief, p. 9) 
they stand to gain they ask this Court to disrupt an 
administrative plan adopted after thousands of pages of 
hearings, involving hundreds of thousands of dollars in 
each milkshed, a plan the Hood producers, non-members 
of co-operatives, voted for 226 to 22 (App. 91) and the 
Whiting producers, likewise non-members, 87 to 20. (App. 
91) Members of cooperatives voted in favor of the plan 
10,744 to 0; individual producers similarly voted 694 to 


L6 


61. (App. 91) There is no principle of equity we know 
of that requires a court to uphold a so-called private 
right at the expense of a great public wrong. ( Greathouse 
v. Bern, 289 U. S. 352, same case below, 61 App. D. C. 
360, 363 F. (2) 137; Morton Salt Co. v. Suppiger Co., 314 
U. S. 488, 492; Burford v. Sun OH Co., 319 U. S. 315, 318- 
319). Indeed the Dern case is strikingly similar to the 
present in that the Court therein said (1) “Petitioners 
are entitled to the relief prayed only if several doubtful 
questions are resolved in their favor” (Op. p. 357); (2) 
it involved an application to a Court to recognize a sup¬ 
posed technical legal right at the expense of great public 
mischief. The Supreme Court held squarely that under 
these circumstances a court of equity in the exercise of 
sound discretion, “may withhold its protection of an un¬ 
doubted legal right.” ( Greathouse v. Bern, 289 U. S. 352, 
359). Thus, the Court said, the equitable remedy: 

“invoked to protect rights to which petitioners are not 
shown to be clearly entitled, would be burdensome to 
the Government without any substantially equivalent, 
benefit to the petitioners ’ ’. (Op. p. 360) 

The Supreme Court continued: 

“The Court, in its discretion may refuse * # * to 
give a remedy which would, work a public injury or 
embarrassment (see Duncan Toicnsite Co. v. Lane, 245 
IT. S. 308, 62 L. Ed. 309, 38 S. Ct. 99, supra; United 
States ex rel. Arant v. Lane, 249 U. S. 367, 63 L. Ed. 
650, 39 S. Ct. 293, supra; Effingham v. Hamilton, 6S 
Miss. 523,10 So. 39; cf. Re Lindgren, supra (232 N. Y. 
66, 133 N. E. 353); McCarthy v. Street Comrs., 188 
Mass. 338, 74 N. E. 659, supra, just as- in its sound dis¬ 
cretion, a court of equity may refuse to enforce or 
protect legal rights, the exercise of which may be 
prejudicial to the public interest. See Seaboard Air 
Line R. Co. v. Atlanta, B. & C. R. Co. (C. C. A. 5th) 
35 F. (2d) 609; Conger v. New York, W. S. & B. R. 
Co., 120 NT Y. 29, 23 N. E. 983; Clarke v. Rochester, 
L. db N. F. R. Co., 18 Barb. 350; Whalen v. Baltimore 
& 0. R. Co., 108 Md. 11, 69 Atl. 390,17 L. B. A. (N. S.) 






17 


130, 129 Am. St. Rep. 423; Curran v. Holyoke Water 
Power Co., 116 Mass. 90; Southern R. Co. v. Franklin 
& P. R. Co., 96 Va. 693, 32 S. E. 485, 44 L. R. A. 297; 
cf. Willard v. Tayloe, 8 Wall. 557, 19 L. Ed. 501. 
Affirmed.” 

It is submitted that no mattei what the. Court found 
as to plaintiffs’ technical legal right, a right sustainable 
only if all doubts be resolved in plaintiffs’ favor, the 
Court should have denied relief on the basis of an en¬ 
tirely disproportionate public injury which will result. 

Also, the fact that the present plaintiffs are in reality 
acting for the benefit of the two largest dairies in New 
England in an attack upon the cooperatives is entitled to 
consideration in connection with plaintiffs claim that this 
is a class suit, and that they act on behalf of themselves 
and all others similarly situated. (App. 2) We emphasize 
that plaintiffs are non-members of the cooperative and, 
hence, cannot act on behalf of members because they do 
not belong to that class, (Rule 23a, Rules of Civil Pro¬ 
cedure, Clark, v. Chase National Bank , 45 Fed. Sup. 820, 
823.; 3 Moore's Fed. Prac. (2d Ed.) p. 3419. Plaintiffs can 
act only for non-members. Even as to non-members, there 
is no showing that other non-members are united in oppos¬ 
ing the deduction; indeed, plaintiffs admitted that all pro¬ 
ducers shipping to Hood and Whiting were not opposed 
to the cooperative deductions. (App. 256, 274.) Under 
the law two-thirds of all producers must be in favor of 
any given Order before it can be adopted. (R. 84, 256) 
Hence, there is considerable doubt whether plaintiffs are 
entitled to contend that they represent even non-members. 
As said in Clark v. Chase National Bank, 45 Fed. Sup. 
820,823: 

“One cannot be a representative of a class institut¬ 
ing litigation on behalf of all other members of the 
class unless his interests are theirs. A conflict in 
interest destroys the representative character of his 
action. It 4 does not afford that protection to absent 
parties which due process requires’. Hansberrv v. 
Lee, 311U. S.32.” 





18 


The record shows that plaintiff Stark’s financial stake 
in the present litigation w T as at the rate of two cents per 
hundredweight of milk delivered by him, around one hun¬ 
dred dollars ($100) as of the end of 1945. (App. 357). 
Plaintiff Walsh’s deductions amounted to around six cents 
a day. (App. 267). Plaintiff Stebbins’ deductions from 
1946 to 1948 inclusive amounted in all to around two- 
hundred and ten dollars ($210) and Stebbins has since 
jointed a cooperative from which he receives benefits. 
(App. 287). This would appear to disqualify Stebbins 
as representative of a class of non-members. Plaintiff 
i Denton from 1941 to 1948 had deductions of around two 
hundred and forty-two dollars ($242). (App. 326). 

It is at the instance of these plaintiffs with these 
meagre financial interests that the court below has over¬ 
turned a comprehensive system of regulation, adopted 
after extensive hearings by the Secretary, on the advice 
of experts in this field. We think the court below abused 
its discretion in entertaining the suit under these circum¬ 
stances and that the suit w'as not in truth and in fact a 
class suit. Under these circumstances where a purported 
1 class suit is not so in fact, it is the duty of the court to 
dismiss. ( Bic?:ford’s, Inc. v. Federal Reserve Bank, 5 
Fed. Supp. S75, 877; Clark v. Chase National Batik, 45 
Fed. Sup. 820, 823). 

We think the present case comes fairly within the fol¬ 
lowing rule: 

“When a suit is brought with a view of affecting 
the rights of third parties, and it is apparent that 
that is its sole object, the suit ceases to be adver¬ 
sary' and becomes collusive.” ( Meeker v. Straat, 38 
Mo. A. 239, 243) See also Ward v. Alsup, 100 Tenn. 
619, 739; Lord v. Veazie, 8 How. 251.) 

The present case is somewhat similar to 17. S. v. Johnson 
319 U. S. 302 except that in the latter case the collusion 
existed on both sides of the case. Here the collusion is one 
side only, it is true, but there is an equal imposition upon 
the court. 




19 


Point II 

Congress Has Authorised the Secretary of Agriculture, 
Upon Proper Findings, Based on Substantial Evidence 
Received at Hearings, to Provide for Payments to 
Producer-Owned and Controlled Co-operative Associa¬ 
tions for Services Rendered to Effectuate the Purposes 
of the Act and of a Marketing Order Issued There¬ 
under. The District Court Erred in Its Contrary 
Holding. 

The act is the Agricultural Adjustment Act (August 
24, 1935, 49 Stat. 750, 7 U. S. C. 601 et seq.), as amended 
by Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (50 Stat. 246. 7 
IT. S. C. 601 et seq.). 

Authority for these payments is contained (A) in a 
specific provision and (B) in general provisions of the 
Act. 

A. The specific provision is Section 8c(7)(D) (Section 
608(7) (D)) which relates to terms common to all orders 
as distinct from Sections 8c(5) and 8c(6) which relate to 
specific terms in milk orders. This provision was re¬ 
ferred to by the Secretary as giving him special authority 
in Finding No. 3 (R. 3). The section authorizes one 
or more terms and conditions in an order and paragraph 
(D) is as follows: 

“(D) Incidental to, and not inconsistent with the 
terms and conditions specified in subsections (5), 
(6) and (7) and necessary to effectuate the other pro¬ 
visions of such order .’ 9 

This is a broad power and has been held to be auxiliary 
to the definite provisions. 1 There are only three limita¬ 
tions to this provision as set forth therein, namely, they 
must be incidental to, not inconsistent with other provi¬ 
sions and necessary to effectuate the order. 


1 United States v. Rock Royal, 307 U. S. 533, 575. 


20 


This Court has held that “incidental” is something 
additional, accessory or collateral and that incidental power 
is additional power although connected with the main sub¬ 
ject 2 

Surely the provision in question meets these tests. It 
is also not inconsistent with the other provisions of the 
order which, as shown by the discussion infra, relate to 
basic mechanics of the order, viz., classified price and 
equalization and the necessary steps to put them into ef¬ 
fect and integrate them. The co-operative provisions 
are distinct and supplementary in their nature and do not 
conflict with the others. They are incidental and appro¬ 
priate provisions left to the discretion of the Secretary 
to be granted after evidence and proper findings. 

The word “necessary” should not be construed as “in¬ 
dispensable, essential or vital.” It is a word to be har¬ 
monized with its text and construed in accordance with 
existing conditions. 2 

The word has been broadly construed and also as to 
embrace all things suitable and proper for carrying into 
execution the powers granted. 4 

The delegation of power to the Secretary to incorporate 
provisions in an order to effectuate the policy of the act 
and the other provisions of the order is not novel. Similar 
provisions with like verbiage or import are contained in 
various federal statutes. 5 


2 Middleton v. Parker, 3 App. Dec. 149, 160; See also Dunvooody 
v. United States, 22 Ct. Cl. 269, 280; Words & Phrases, VoL 20 p. 
423; Dickey v. Raisin Proration Zone, 24 Cal. (2d) 796, 151 P. (2d) 
505. 

3 Armour & Co. V. Wantock, 323 U. S. 126, 129, 180. 

4 United States v. Denver & Rio Grande R. Co., 150 U. S. 1; 
General Investment Co. v. Bethlehem Steel Corp ., 248 F. 303, 311 
(D. C. N. Y.). 

5 §§159(b) and 160(c), National Labor Rel. Act, Tit. 29 U. S. C.; 
49 Stat. 453; Commodity Exchange Act, §12a(5). Tit. 7 U. S. C.; 
49 Stat. 1500 upheld in Nichols & Co. v. Secretary of Agriculture, 




Regulations of the administrative board pursuant to 
snch provisions in the National Labor Relations Aet have 
been upheld.* 

Indeed in the Phelps Dodge case (cited below) the Court 
pointed out at page 191 that the effectuation clause was 
“the central clue to the Board’s powers,” and it held that 
Congress could not define the whole gamut of remedies 
to effectuate the policy of the Act and leaving the adapta¬ 
tion of means to end to the empiric process of administra¬ 
tion, had committed the exercise of the process to the 
Board. Also that Courts should not curtail the exercise 
of such a power nor “enter the allowable area of the 
Board’s discretion” after a determination by an adminis¬ 
trative agency upon findings. 

In Yakus v. United States, 321 U. S. 414, 427, in con¬ 
struing the Price Control Act, the Court held that the 
Administrator was given wide discretion as to the condi¬ 
tions of an order (p. 438); that he had power to formu¬ 
late subsidiary administrative policies within the statutory 
framework and that it was proper for Congress to give 
an officer ample latitude in determining the necessary 
conditions (p. 425). It was also held in United States v. 
Rock Royal, 307 U. S. 533, 574, that it was proper to 
delegate authority to make regulations which would im¬ 
plement the general provisions of the statute.* 


131 F. 2d 651, 658; Bituminous Coal Conservation Act, §833(d). 
Tit. 15 U. S. C.; 50 Stat. 77; Tobacco Inspection Act, §511-m. Tit 
7 U. S. C.; 49 Stat. 734; Agricultural Adjustment Act, §§608(2) 
(a)(8) also 608a(2), Tit. 7 U. S. C.; 48 Stat. 34, 672; Emergency 
Price Control Act of 1942, §2(a), 50 U. S. C. (Appendix 25) 56 Stat. 
23; Fair Labor Standards Act, 29 U. S. C. A. §208(f), construed in 
Gemsco v. Walling, 324 U. S. 244, 255. 

c Frank Bros. v. National Labor Rel. Board, 321 U. S. 702, 704; 
National Labor Rel. Board v. Hearst Publications, 322 U. S. Ill, 
131-2; Southern S. S. Co. v. National Labor Rel. Board, 315 U. S. 
31, 46; Phelps Dodge V. National Labor Rel. Board, 313 U. S. 177; 

7 See also Lichter v. United States, 334 U. S. 742, 785. 


22 


A similar delegation of power was involved under the 
Second War Powers Act of 1942 involving the power of 
the President to issue regulations to effectuate the policies 
of the Act. The War Food Administrator established 
quotas of milk, cream and by-products for sale by handlers 
and required that the handlers pay expenses of enforce¬ 
ment of the regulation by a per hundred-weight as¬ 
sessment. Apparently there was no direct authorization 
for this and reliance was placed upon the discretionary 
power of the Administrator to effectuate the policies of 
the Act. The District Court held the assessment to be 
unauthorized but this decision was reversed by the Cir¬ 
cuit Court of Appeals which held the assessment to be 
necessary to fill out the details of Congressional action, 
that the Administrator had the power to ascertain facts 
and apply the statute to the result and that it was an in¬ 
cident proper to the regulation of the industry. A peti¬ 
tion for writ of certiorari was denied. 8 

The Court below while apparently considering that the 
co-operative payment, provision in the order was incon¬ 
sistent on its face with other provisions of the order, 
considered the words “incidental” and “necessary” purely 
abstractly from the standpoint of legal definition and 
w’holly ignored the specific findings of fact by the Secretary 
that such provision was incidental, necesary to effectuate 
the other provisions of the order and not inconsistent (7 
CFR, 1941 Supp. 904.0). This was improper and espe¬ 
cially so because the judgment of the Secretary in this 
regard was not subject to review, 9 and it has been held 
that such a determination is one of fact, 10 and that there 


R Warehime V. Varney, 54 F. Supp. 907, D. C. N. D., Ohio, E. D., 
147 F. 2d 238, 6 C. A., and 325 U. S. 882. 

9 United States v. Bush & Co., 310 U. S. 371 and National Labor 
Relations Board v. P. Lorillard Co., 314 U. S. 512. 

10 Kalamazoo Auto Sales Co. v. Travelers Ins. Co., 222 Mich. 74, 
198 N. W. 579; 




23 


is a presumption of the existence of facts justifying the 
specific exercise. 11 

The duty of the Secretary to insert provisions to ef¬ 
fectuate the policies of the Act are contained in Sections 
8c(3), 8c(4) as well as 8c(7)(D) and it was held in 
United States v. Kelly, 55 F. 2d 67, 70 (C. C. A. 2) that 
such a duty carried by implication every reasonable means 
necessary to effectuate the desired end. 

Unless the determination as to what provisions of an 
order are incidental and necessary be left to the Secretary 
as an expert, his powers will be greatly curtailed. His 
findings, unless clearly outside the scope of the Act or a 
clear case of abuse of discretion, are conclusive.” 

There was a second finding in 1944 by the Acting Direc¬ 
tor of Food Distribution who had taken over the duties 
of the Secretary of Agriculture as to orders by direction 
of the President. This finding is set forth in 9 F. R. 3059 
(issue of March 21, 1944) and in part is as follows: 

“The present plan of payments to cooperatives, 
which became effective August 1, 1941, was based on 
the consideration that to achieve the benefits to all 
producers which the order is designed to provide two 
types of activity by producers’ cooperative marketing 
organizations are desirable—(1) presentation of evi¬ 
dence at hearings concerning the needs of producers 
with respect to prices for milk and differentials to 
reflect handling costs to furnish an adequate basis for 
constructive amendments to the order, and (2) as¬ 
sumption of reponsibility for a reserve of milk to 
meet the irregular needs of distributors which is es¬ 
sential in a market which provides market-wide equali¬ 
zation among all producers of the total value of the 
milk. Further, it is recognized that allowances for 
costs associated with providing services to the market 

11 Thompson v. Consolidated Gas Utilities Corp., 300 U. S. 55, 69. 

12 Gray v. Powell, 314 U. S. 402, 411, 412; Gemsco V. Walling, 324 
U. S. 224; American Power & Light Co. V. Sec., 329 U. S. 90, 112. 


24 


should be separated from the allowance which re¬ 
flects the additional cost of receiving milk at country 
plants compared to receiving it directly at city plants. 
From these considerations it was concluded that pro¬ 
vision for payments to cooperative associations is 
considered necessary to equitably apportion the total 
value of milk among producers. The testimony in 
support of the proposal to completely eliminate this 
feature of the order does not show that these con¬ 
siderations were substantially erroneous.” 

The reference in such finding to the allowances for costs 
associated with handling surplusses of the market is ap¬ 
parently in reference to the fact that in some of the orders 
prior to that of 1941 there was an extra charge allowed 
to co-operatives for handling milk and that this was 
dropped at the time of the insertion of the provisions 
for co-operative payments in 1941. (Affidavit of Thomas 
G. Stitts App. 77). 

B. General Provisions.—These are Secs. 1, 2, 8c(18)— 
[(601), (602), (608c) (18)] of the 1937 Act and 10(b)(1) 
of the 1935 Act, Sec. 610(b)(1) 49 Stat. 801. They relate 
to the general purpose and intent of Congress. They 
must be read with Secs. 8c(5), 8c(7)(D) as part of the 
Act because the Act must be interpreted as a harmonious 
whole. 13 The legislative policy and purpose are control¬ 
ling. 14 They control over literal words. 13 

Secs. 1, 2 and 8c (18) should be read together inasmuch 
as they relate to prices to be paid to producers and ex¬ 
press the intent of Congress. They are in fact a full 
change of the 1935 Act which based such prices on the 
so-called “parity” plan, to prices resulting from orderly 


13 Great Northern Ry. v. United States, 315 U. S. 262, 272; D. 
Ginsberg & Sons V. Popkin, 285 U. S. 244. 

14 United States v. Congress of Industrial Organizations, 325 U. 
S. 106, 112: Securities & Ex. Comm. v. C. M. Joiner L. Corp., 320 
U. S. 344, 857; Lichter v. United States, 334 U. S. 742, 785. 

13 United States v. American Trucking Asso., 810 U. S. 534, 542-4. 


25 


marketing (Secs. 1-2) and take into consideration some 
costs of production, economic factors affecting supply and 
demand and prices which will insure an ample supply for 
the market (8c(18)). 

Nowhere in Sec. 8c(5) as to prices to producers or to 
dealers is there any mention of factors relating to or¬ 
derly marketing or prices which will insure an ample 
supply. The adjustments there mentioned take no cogniz¬ 
ance of them. As discussed infra under Point III, the 
co-operative i>ayment provision was closely connected with 
such factors. 

Section 10(b) (1) is as follows: 

“The Secretary in the administration of this title, 
shall accord such recognition and encouragement to 
producer-owned and producer-controlled co-operative 
associations as will be in harmony with the policy 
toward co-operative associations set forth in existing 
acts of Congress, and as will tend to promote efficient 
methods of marketing and distribution.” 

Aside from special privileges for co-operatives under 
the Capper-Volstead Act in relation to restraints of trade; 
(42 Stat. 388, 7 U. S. C. Sec. 291), the Co-operative Mar¬ 
keting Act of 1926 (44 Stat. 802-3, 7 U. S. C. Sec. 451-5) 
in regard to promoting co-operatives and exchange of in¬ 
formation, exemption from Income Tax by Sec. 231 of 
Income Tax Act of 1926, 44 Stat. 9 (now Sec. 101, 26 
IT. S. C,); there is the Agricultural Marketing Act of 
1929 (46 Stat. 11) (now 12 TJ. S. C., Sec. 1141) in which 
the policy of Congress was declared to be promotion of 
effective merchandising of agricultural commodities by 
encouraging the organization of co-operatives for greater 
unity of effort in marketing and also controlling surplusses 
so as to prevent depression of prices. 

The reports of the Congressional Committees on the 
1935 Act H. E. 1241, pp. 9-11 and Sen. 1011, pp. 9-11, 
pointed out that the provisions of Sec. 8c of the Act em- 


26 


bodied the methods employed by co-operative associa¬ 
tions. Among these methods apparently were a check off 
to a Chicago milk co-operative (Pure Milk Association) of 
14 per cwt. on the milk of all producers 'whether or not 
members of the Association, later increased to 24 and 
then to 3^ per cwt. for an adjustment fund to take care 
of surplus and advertising and the check-off in the Twin- 
City License, p. 28, infra. 

There is also Congressional history in regard to Section 
10(b)(1). Apparently at the hearing before the House 
Agricultural Committee on the original bill, Mr. Chester 
Davis of the Department of Agriculture in answer to a 
question admitted that it was not the purpose of the 
proposed provision to give preferential treatment to co¬ 
operatives. However, later at the hearing before the Sen¬ 
ate Committee on Agriculture & Forestry, 75th Cong. 1st 
Sess., on S. 1807, pp. 45-6 Mr. Davis while stating that it 
was not the intention to discriminate in favor of co-oper¬ 
atives said it might be necessary in case of milk orders 
and specifically said: “I can conceive of that in the case 
of milk. I would not like to have our power questioned.” 
Possibly as a result of Mr. Davis’ statement to the House 
Committee both House and Senate Reports (H. R. 1241, 
p. 13 and Sen. No. 1011, p. 26) stated in reference to this 
section: 

“It is not intended by this language to discriminate 
against other handlers, processors, or dealers, but it 
has been found from experience that the participation 
by local committees and associations of producers has 
been of material value in administering the program.” 

A rider -was adopted by the House prohibiting such a 
discrimination against other producers, processors and 
handlers and this was stricken out by the Senate. The 


ie See Report of Federal Trade Commission re sale and distribu¬ 
tion of Milk in Chicago Sales Area, House Doc. No. 451, 74th Cong 
2nd Sess., p. 47. 


27 


House accepted the Senate version. 17 Thus Congress after 
consideration struck out a limitation which would have 
expressly prohibited the co-operative payment provision. 
While this action is not conclusive, it is to be considered. 1 * 

The Courts have also recognized the public policy in 
regard to co-operatives. 10 

The Committee Reports, supra, are also important in 
regard to their recognition of the value of services by 
local associations in administering federal programs. They 
express the intent of Congress. Such reports are relevant 
in interpretation of a statute, no matter how clear words 
may appear on superficial examination. 20 

Prior to the passage of the Agricultural Marketing 
Agreement Act of 1937, the State of New York amended 
its Milk Control Act and authorized (in paragraph 9 of 
§258-m) deductions for marketing services by co-opera¬ 
tives 21 and later this was amended to make clear that such 
deductions should be paid to co-operative associations for 
services by them. 22 

Federal Order No. 27 for the New York area issued in 
August 1938 contained provisions for co-operative pay¬ 
ments. The Order was issued not only pursuant to the 
provisions of 8c(5) but also pursuant to Section 10(1) of 
the Federal Act which authorized .uniform regulations and 
concurrent orders to carry out federal and state pro- 


17 House Conference Committee Rept. No. 1747, Aug. 12, 1935, p. 
28. 

18 Fox v. Standard Oil Co., 294 U. S. 87, 96; United States V. 
United Machinery Co., 64 F. 138, 174 (D. C. E. D. Mo.) ; Cudahy 
Packing Co. V. Holland 315 U. S. 357, 366. 

19 United States v. Rock Royal, 307 U. S. 533, 563; Tigner V. 

Texas, 310 U. S. 141, 145-7; Liberty Warehouse Co. v. Burley 
Tobacco Co., 276 U. S. 71, 93, 96. . 

20 Harrison v. Northern Trust Co., 317 U. S. 476, 479. 

21 Chap. 383 of the Laws of 1937 in effect May 19. 

22 Par. 11 of Sec. 258-m, as amended by Chap. 760 of the Laws of 
1939. 




26 


grams and pursuant to an agreement between the federal 
Secretary of Agriculture and the state Commissioner of 
Agriculture and Markets ( H . B. Hood & Sons v. DuMond, 
69 S. Ct. 657,666). 

Also the Indiana Milk Control Law of 1935 (Chap. 281, 
Par. 11 of Sec. 5) authorized check-offs to either local milk 
committees or co-operatives for marketing services. 

The marketing agreement license for the Twin City 
Area—No. 5, issued in August 1933, of which the Court 
can take judicial cognizance, 23 contained provisions where¬ 
by dealers who purchased milk of non-members of the 
co-operative association should pay such Association the 
difference between the price which the Association paid its 
members and the class price for the milk as a service charge 
for regulating the supply. This license and agreement was 
one of those ratified by the 1937 statute. 

Point III 

The Court Below Erroneously Concluded That the Secre¬ 
tary Exceeded His Statutory Authority in Inserting 
in the Order the Provision for Deductions for Pay¬ 
ment to Co-operative Associations. 

The opinion of the Court holds (a) that the statute did 
not expressly authorize such deductions, (b) that they were 
not “incidental” provisions, (c) that they were not neces¬ 
sary to effectuate the other provisions of the order, (d) 
that they could not be considered as “not inconsistent” 
with the other provisions of the order, (e) that the admin¬ 
istrative interpretation was not of sufficient weight to be 
•considered and (f) that the legislative history of the Act 
was illuminating and adverse. 

While it is true that there is no authority in specific 
words in the Act for the questioned provision, there is, as 


53 Caha v. United States, 182 U. S. 211, 221; Lilly v. Grand Trunk 
Western Ry^ 317 U. S. 481, 488; Thorsch v. Miller, 5 F. 2d 118, 121. 


29E 


pointed out in Point II, supra, authority therefor in the 
various sections of the Act. The Court apparently relied 
to a large extent in use of the words “no others” in Sec¬ 
tion 8c(5) as limiting authority to the specific clauses.au¬ 
thorized in 8c(5)(A)(B). However, the Court apparently 
overlooked, the words preceding these words which were 
“except as provided in sub-section (7).” These latter 
words are controlling and inasmuch as they are in the 
overfall or controlling part of 8c(5) they apply to all the 
provisions of such- sub-section. The Court also referred 
to the word “only” in 8c(5)(B)(ii) in connection with 
adjustment of prices .toproducers^shaving a similar*effect 
as “no others.” This conclusion, is contrary to the ra¬ 
tionale of the section as disclosed by. the background, of the 
Act and practical operation of the order. 

Federal regulation of the milk industry became neces¬ 
sary because of the interstate commerce handicaps of state 
control. New York State was largely the instigator of 
these state controls- 23 as a result of an intensive legislative 
investigation summarized in Nebbia v. New York, 291 U. S. 
500. Other states- followed its example. Because state 
control was held ineffective on interstate shipments in 
Baldwin v. Seelig, 294 U. S. 511, the Governors of New 
York and other states appealed to Congress for a federal 
act. 28 State regulation used what is commonly known as 
the classified price for prices to dealers and equalization 
of prices to producers was advisable to implement the 
classified price plan and prevent price discrimination be¬ 
tween producers because of varying uses of milk at differ¬ 
ent values by the various dealers to whom the milk was 
delivered. 27 

Section 8c(5)(A) was intended solely to provide a basis- 
for pricing to dealers, that is, the classified price plan,, and 

25 Chap. 158, Laws of 1933; 

28 Vol. 79, Cong. Rec. No. 144, p. 11583. 

17 United States v. Rock Royal, SOT U. 3-. 525, 571-22 





30 


Section 8c(5)(B)(C) for a uniform price to producers 
(uniform meaning the same base price for milk delivered 
to fluid plants and for that delivered to manufacturing 
plants) through equalization of all sales. 28 

These features were an adoption of state experience and 
the use of “only” was to insure that these two basic prin¬ 
ciples and these only should be used in orders. 

“Congress by stating expressly its primary ends 
does not deny resort to the means necessary to achieve 
them.” 

Gemsco v. Walling, 334 U. S. 244, 262. 

The co-operative payment features were not basic prin¬ 
ciples and were incidental thereto. Secondly, the adjust¬ 
ments referred to in sub. (ii) of 8 e(5)(B) are those made 
in the payments to the individual producers after the uni¬ 
form or pool price has been determined from the combined 
net sales to all dealers. For example, one is for butterfat 
and bacteria tests which, of course, can relate only to the 
individual producer’s deliveries and are not a general 
expense to be deducted from the blended price. The other 
adjustment is on account of differentials to the individual 
producer on account of location of farm with respect to 
point of delivery or by reason of his locality being nearer 
the market where a higher price has been customarily paid 
as distinguished from distant points where a lower price 
has prevailed. Thus the word “only” was used to limit 
that kind of adjustments. It had no reference to general 
deductions from the blended price, and in any event it was 
subject to the general exception which permitted provisions 
authorized by Section 8c(7). The “further adjustment” 
next mentioned probably relates to what is commonly 
known as “base rating plan.” It concerns only additions 
to or deductions from the checks of individual producers 
on account of deliveries in compliance with or in excess of 
production quotas, if any, fixed by an order. 


58 S. Kept. No. 1011, 74th Cong. 1st Sess., pp. 9-11, H. R. 1241, 
pp. 9-11. 


31: 


All of the foregoing listed deductions are made from the 
producers’ checks after determination of the blended or 
pool price to be distributed to producers. This distinction 
was made in Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288, 300-1, and a 
similar deduction for a revolving fund was mentioned 
there. 

The ruling of the Court in this matter would seem 
squarely in conflict with the decision in Green Valley v. 
United States 29 where under the terms of Order No. 4 
there was a price differential in favor of co-operative asso¬ 
ciations. Also to that in Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Ander¬ 
son 30 where a quota on outside milk was imposed in pricing 
to dealers and thus the word “only” in 8c(5)(A) was in 
effect disregarded. 

An equally serious objection to the opinion of the Court 
below is that the heading of 8c(7) is “Terms Common to 
All Orders.” Reading this with the exception of 8c(5), 
there is a clear implication that nothing contained in 
8c(5)(A)(B), unless expressly inconsistent, shall prevent 
incidental provisions under 8c(7)(D); also the first sen¬ 
tence of (7) declares in effect that all milk orders shall 
contain one or more of the terms there listed. There was 
no inconsistency. Claims were made in the Court below 
that paragraphs (E) and (F) of 8c(5) were inconsistent 
with the deduction provision. (E) relates solely to deduc¬ 
tions of benefit to the individual producers, viz., general 
market information as to sales, prices, etc. and checking 
weights and tests of the producers and obtaining security 
for amounts due from the dealers. Such checking and 
furnishing of security would be of no benefit to producers 
of another dealer. On the other hand the deduction for a 
co-operative as outlined in the Report of the Food Admin¬ 
istrator, supra, (p. 23) was dual in nature. It provided 
for remuneration to co-operatives for services in the prep- 

29 108 F. 2d 342 (C. C. A. 1). 

30 157 F. 2d 87 (C. C. A. 8), Cert, denied 329 U. S. 788. 



32 


aration of orders and amendments thereto and famishing 
reserves of milk to supply the market Unorganized pro¬ 
ducers are wholly unable to present to the Secretary any 
rational marketing programs. They have neither cohesion, 
knowledge of marketing problems, experience in marketing 
or legal and technical experts. On the other hand, the co¬ 
operatives have all of these/ This latter is squarely within 
the realm of orderly marketing and furnishing of ample 
supply to the market. In this regard there was uncontra¬ 
dicted evidence in this case that the smaller dealers would 
not buy their supplies in the short season of production 
from the big dealers and it was necessary for the co¬ 
operatives to furnish them a large part of their supplies 
which in turn involved the handling of surplus by co-opera- 
atives. Thus these services were found to be necessary 
to effectuate the other provisions of the order. They were 
in fact connected with the purposes of the Act set forth 
in Sections 1, 2 and 8c(18), including adequate supplies 
for the market. The terms of an order must tend to 
effectuate the policy of the Act. 8c(4). 

Furthermore (E) has two subdivisions, (i) being limited 
to producers for whom the services mentioned and not 
furnished by a co-operative, while (ii) is not so limited. 
It relates to security for payments to producers. This is 
one of the express purposes of the deductions here in¬ 
volved. 

Provisions similar to those authorized by (i) were con¬ 
tained in the Boston 1936 order and in other orders and 
licenses and are in the present Cincinnati and Dayton- 
Springfield orders. The Chicago 1933 license contained 
provisions for deductions to be paid to an independent 
agency for advertising and to care for credit losses and in 
the Twin-City 1933 license, a similar provision on account 
of advertising. In both was a statement that such pay¬ 
ments “shall be deemed part of the price paid to pro¬ 
ducers.’ * The fact that such provisions were ratified by 
Congress in 1937 shows intent that such kind of deductions 


33 


and payments were proper. Such ratification made such 
deductions lawful. 31 House Report No. 1241, p. 11 and 
Senate No. 1011, p. 11, specifically mentioned both kind of 
services mentioned in (i) and (ii). 

As to (F) a co-operative under its contract with pro¬ 
ducers may blend sales proceeds both under and outside 
of a federal order. The impleaded defendant here does 
this and but for (F) a serious question would arise as to 
impairment of contracts. To obviate this some federal 
licenses and various state Acts contained a similar provi¬ 
sion.” 

The Committee Reports, supra, (p. 25) stated that 
the provision in (F) was to safeguard co-operative con¬ 
tracts with producers. (F) relates only to distributive 
payments by a co-operative to its producers and is not 
related to 8c(7)(D). 

As discussed previously (p. 23) the determination as to 
necessity of a provision to effectuate the other provisions 
of the order was one for determination of the Secretary 
upon evidence and findings and not for the Court unless 
wholly arbitrary and without substantial evidence, neither 
of which conditions exist here. 

The subjects of administrative interpretation and legis¬ 
lative history will be discussed infra, Points IV and V. 

In considering the word “necessary 1 ’ it should be noted 
that the members of the co-operatives bear the extra ex¬ 
penses of their associations in servicing the market and 
maintaining able and experienced staffs to aid in prepara- 


81 Svxiyne & Hoyt V. United States, 300 U. S. 297, 302; United 
States V. Von Clemm, 136 F. 2d 969, 970 (C. C. A. 2). 

82 Chicago License No. 30, issued December 31, 1934; Dubuque 
License No. 94, issued November 30, 1934; Des Moines License No. 
31, issued December 31, 1934; Sec. 19 Pennsylvania Act of 1933 
(No. 37); Sec. 313 of Chap. 168, New York Laws of 1933: Sec. 16 
of Oregon Act of 1933; Sec. 11 of Connecticut Act of 1933; Sec. 
l(i) of Art. VI of Chap. 169 of New Jersey Laws of 1933; Sec. 21 
of Indiana Act of 1936; Chap. 281 and Sec. 20 of Ohio Act of 1933. 


34 


tion of orders. Thus these members get a lower price for 
their milk than the non-co-operative producers. Therefore, 
a counteracting differential (co-operative payment) must 
be created to prevent “market pool equalization” from 
placing the co-operative producers in a less favorable po¬ 
sition than that enjoyed by non-co-operative producers; 
otherwise, such a situation would threaten the very exist¬ 
ence of the organizations which designed the statutory and 
regulatory program, viz., the co-operatives. 

In applying a rigid leveling process by a regulation, 
such as market pool equalization, some countervailing 
adjustments are proper and in fact necessary to keep from 
destroying the basic organizations of the beneficiaries of 
the regulation. 

Correctly viewed, co-operative payments are a mere 
refinement and perfection of equalization. 

Control of milk is a vital feature of orderly marketing 
and adequate supply for the market. Unorganized pro¬ 
ducers have no control of their milk after delivery to the 
dealer who may, at will, ship to Boston or any other market 
under Order No. 4 or otherwise, wherever higher prices 
are obtainable. Co-operatives, however, as a condition of 
their payments must have control of their milk in order to 
take care of the market. 33 

Point IV 

The Secretary’s Order Was An Administrative Interpreta¬ 
tion of His Authority Which Is Entitled to Great 
Weight. 

A provision for co-operative payments in the New York 
order was inserted in August 1938 or within about fourteen 
months from the enactment of the Marketing Act of 1937. 34 

“ Sec. 904.9(a) of Boston Order; Sec. 5 of Art. VII of New York 
Order of 1938; Appendix 

54 Sec. 5 of Art. VII set forth in United States v. Rock Royal 
Co-op^ 307 U. S. 533, footnote No. 14. Judicial notice can be taken 
of these orders. Caha v. United States, 152 U. S. 211, 221; Lilly 
v. Grand Trunk Ry., 317 U. S. 481, 488. 






35 


Similar provisions in the Boston Order were inserted in 
1941, in the Cincinnati Order in 1944 and in the Dayton- 
Springfield Order in 1945. Each of these provisions is still 
in effect although in somewhat modified form. Thus the 
New York Order provision was a substantially contempo¬ 
raneous interpretation made by an expert charged with 
responsibility of setting the machinery in motion and 
making it work; and it has been in effect nearly eleven 
years; also it was his staff which presented the original bill 
to Congress, all of which features add weight to the inter¬ 
pretation. 33 

The Court below (App. 149) refused to accept this in¬ 
terpretation because (a) it was not one continued over a 
long period. The cases cited, however, seem to have been 
impliedly overruled by the later decisions which apparently 
base the test on contemporaneous interpretation continued 
only as to consistency, and (b) because an administrative 
officer cannot be allowed to interpret his own powers. 
Again the case cited seems to have been impliedly over¬ 
ruled by almost constant practice of administrative officials 
and decisions. 36 

The 1938 interpretation by the Secretary involved not 
only the provision relating to co-operative payments in¬ 
serted in the New York order but the explanation thereof 
by his department set forth in Appendix I, present brief, 
which in part states that co-operative associations render 
services of benefit to all producers in securing highest 


35 Billings v. Truesdell, 321 U. S. 542, 552; White v. Winchester 
Country Club, 315 U. S. 32, 41; Great Northern Railway V. United 
States, 315 U. S. 262, 275; Gray V. PoweU, 314 U. S. 402, 412-413; 
Gemsco v. Walling, 324 U. S. 244; Virginia E. L. & P. Co. V. N. L. 
R . Bd., 319 U. S. 533, 539, 540. 

36 See Fleming v. Mohawk Wrecking & Lumber Co., 331 U. S. Ill, 
116; United States V. American Trucking Association, supra; Tagg 
& Moorehead V. United States, 280 U. S. 420, 435; Illinois Natural 
Gas Co. v. Central Illinois P. L. Co., 314 U. S. 498, 509, where 
apparently similar powers were exercised. 




36 


utilization of milk under the order and supplying dealers 
with milk when needed. 


Point V 

Subsequent Legislative History Supports the Validity of 

the Co-operative Payment Provision Involved Here. 

Subsequent history is a valuable aid in interpretation 
of statutes. 37 

In the Rock Royal case, early in 1938, the District 
Court 3,i in a sweeping decision held both the Act and the 
New York order to be invalid. Although the question was 
not raised by the pleadings or on the trial, the Court in 
its opinion stated that the co-operative payment provisions 
in the New York order were not expressly authorized by 
the Act The Supreme Court in its general reversal held 
that the defendants were not in a position to raise this 
question. 

In view of these decisions, in 1940 in Senate Bill No. 
3426 by Mr. Gillette which contained numerous amend¬ 
ments to the Agricultural Adjustment Act, a provision 
was inserted in Section 4 amending Section 8c(5)(C) by 
adding a provision (i) specifically authorizing co-operative 
payments and (ii) payments to handlers for disposal of 
surplus. The first part is as follows: 

“ ‘Providing further (i) reasonable compensation 
(to be paid out of any pool or fund) established under 
this paragraph (C) of subsection (5), as determined 
by the Secretary, to bona fide cooperative marketing 
associations, all of whose operations are under the 
full control of milk producers, for services rendered 
to producers of milk or its products covered by the 
order by performing such marketing functions speci¬ 
fied therein as the Secretary determines will tend to 
effectuate the declared policy of this Act, including 

17 Great Northern Ry. V. United States, 315 U. S. 262, 277. 

s * 26 F. Supp. 534 (N. D. N. Y.); 307 U. S. 533. 






37 


but not by way of limitation, h an dl i n g of surplus 
milkj or making available to the market a sufficient 
supply of milk at all times: Provided, however, That 
no such compensation shall be paid to any cooper¬ 
ative association which does not comply with the ap¬ 
plicable provisions of the order: * * *” 

Apparently this was a revision of H. R. 6208 intro¬ 
duced in the First Session of the 76th Congress, the Gillette 
bill being introduced in the Third Session. 

Hearings were held on the House bill by its Committee 
on Agriculture on June 1, and June 2, 1939, and it was 
there pointed out that the legality of the provisions of 
the New York order for co-operative payments had been 
raised in the Rock Royal case; that a decision by the 
United States Supreme Court was expected shortly there¬ 
after (the decision actually was handed down on June 5, 
1939) and that one reason for the amendment proposed 
as to co-operative payments was a specific provision 
authorizing it be inserted in the law (see testimony of 
Fred H. Sexauer in Hearing Record, p. 25). 

The hearing before the Senate Committee on Agricul¬ 
ture and Forestry on the Gillette bill was held on April 1, 
and April 4, 1940, or a few months after the decision in 
the Rock Royal case, and not only were reasons for sup¬ 
porting payments to co-operatives set forth by witnesses, 
but suggestions were also made that specific authority 
therefor be given in the statute (see statements by Mr. 
Sexauer, R. p. 70, by E. W. Gaumnitz, Director, Division 
of Marketing and Marketing Agreements, Department of 
Agriculture, p. 53 (Appendix III, present brief) Letter of 
Secretary Wallace, p. 5 and statement of the Department 
of Agriculture at page 26, which states, in substance, that 
the purpose of the amendment was “In order to make 
definite and certain the Secretary’s authority in this re¬ 
gard and to settle the question that insufficient standards 
are spelled out in the act to guide the Secretary, it is re¬ 
garded as essential that the law be amended in the 



38 


respects contemplated by Section 4 of S. 3426.” This 
statement also went into details as to the nature of the 
sendees rendered by co-operatives. 

The Senate Committee on Agriculture and Forestry 
made a report on the Gillette bill and an abstract of such 
report is contained in Appendix IV, present brief. The 
bill was passed by the Senate, but apparently no action 
was taken by the House. The Congressional Record of 
September IS, 1940, 76th Cong. 3rd Sess., Vol. 86, Part 
11, pages 12,255-12,266, and of September 30, 1940, page 
12^80, contains significant facts in regard to this bill. 
There were 16 sections in the bill as reported and, as 
shown in the Senate Committee Report, Senator Gillette 
stated there were no objections to Sections 1 -14, which 
included the provisions as to milk. The remaining sec¬ 
tions related to fruits, vegetables and canning crops. 
These latter, as shown by statements of farm organiza¬ 
tions endorsing the bill (p. 12,265) were very contro¬ 
versial, as shown by the records of the hearings in both 
houses, and especially so in the House. On the other 
hand, the record of the Senate hearings show’s that there 
was no opposition to the sections relating to milk and 
that the farm organizations were unanimous in approval 
thereof. Apparently, however, because of the controversy 
in the House as to the other sections stricken from the 
Senate Bill, no action w T as taken in the House. 

It is to be noted that Section 14 of the Gillette bill con¬ 
tains a provision similar to Section 4 of the Agricultural 
Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 ratifying and approv¬ 
ing all existing orders and this, of course, included Order 
No. 27 for the New York area which contains a co-oper¬ 
ative payment provision. 

It is submitted that this Congressional history should 
be conclusive as to the intent of Congress, especially in 
these four particulars: 





39 


1. That authority for co-operative payments is actually 
contained in Sections 8c(5) and 8c(7)(D) of the Act: 

2. The bill sets forth two essentials of co-operative 
marketing, namely, handling of surplus and servicing the 
market by ample supplies in short periods, which are serv¬ 
ices rendered by co-operatives. These essentials are the 
same as set forth in Point II of this brief. 

3. The report and statement on the floor by Senator 
Schwellenbach, who represented the Committee, shows 
that such services by co-operatives are essential to orderly 
marketing and to effectuate milk orders. 

4. That the purpose of Section 4 was merely to clarify 
the authority for co-operative payments and provide stand¬ 
ards therefor. 

It is to be noted that the Committee on Agriculture and 
Forestry was the Committee which approved the 1935 and 
1937 Acts and that the 1940 proceedings took place about 
five years after the passage of the 1935 Act. 

In Sioux Tribe of Indians v. United States, 316 U. S. 
317, 329, the Court said in regard to a similar Senate 
Report and statement: 

“This statement by the Committee which reported 
the General Allotment Act of 1887, made within five 
years of its passage, is virtually conclusive as to the 
significance of that Act.” 

And in Porter v. Murray, 156 F. 2d 781, 785, the Court 
said: 

“The fact that this is a report of a committee of 
only one House of Congress does not deprive it of 
considerable weight.” 

Contcmporaneous History: 

In the letter of the Chairman of the Federal Trade 
Commission to the House, dated January 5, 1937 (House 
Doc. 94) p. 34 is the following: 



40 


“Producers* cooperative organizations in the areas 
investigated have greatly improved conditions in 
dairy farming and have probably obtained better 
prices for milk than the producers could have ob¬ 
tained without such organizations.** 

These are a part of the services recognized in the co¬ 
operative payment provision. 

And on page 36 is the following: 

“It has been established by the investigation that 
the activities of most of the bona-fide independent 
cooperative organizations have greatly benefited milk 
producers. The activities of these organizations 
should be broadened and encouragement given to the 
extension of such activities as are authorized by the 
various Federal and State laws. • • *** 

The amendment to the New York Act, subdivision 11 
of Section 258-m (Chap. 383, Laws of 1937, amended by 
Chap. 760, Laws of 1939) specifically authorized pay¬ 
ments for co-operative activities under milk control orders. 
Also Section 3 of Chap. 760 of the Laws of 1939 ratified 
New York Official Order No. 126 (concurrent with and 
identical to Federal Order No. 126) and Order No. 27 
(regulating the handling of milk in the Buffalo marketing 
area) both of which orders contained co-operative pay¬ 
ment clauses. 

Because of the fact that the Federal Act was largely 
taken from the New York Act, and in order to have uni¬ 
formity in control, as expressed in subdivision (i) of Sec¬ 
tion 10 of the Federal Act, the provisions of the New York 
Act should be given strong consideration. 3 ® 

In the Parker case, supra, the Court in construing this 
provision of the Act said: 


39 Parker V. Broxon, 317 U. S. 341, 354; Hoffman V. Palmer, 129 
F. 2d 976, 985, afPd. 318 U. S. 109; Metropolitan R. Co. v. Moore, 
121 U. S. 558, 572; Merchants Exchange v. Missouri, 248 U. S. 365, 
366; Matter of Cregan, 275 N. Y. 337; Bimbaum V. United States, 
107 F. 2d 885, 887. 


41 


“• # * The Act contemplates that each sovereign 
shall operate ‘in its own sphere but can exert its 
authority in conformity rather than in conflict with 
that of the other.’ ” 

In other words, the Secretary should not issue orders 
in conflict with New York laws. 

Furthermore, as to the New York Market Order No. 27, 
the Secretary acted under said sect. 10(i) and in accord¬ 
ance with an agreement with the Commissioner of Agri¬ 
culture and Markets of New York State. 

It was a joint or complementary order with the New 
York Order issued after joint hearings. See Preamble to 
Order and Sect. 1 of Art. X. 

The agreement specifically provided fo-' uniformity in 
essential terms of the orders. Thus in case of Order No. 
27, we have use not only of the provisions of 8c(7)(D) of 
the Act but also of 10(i) in issuance of the order. Sect. 
254^n of the New York Act authorizes such action by the 
state commissioner. 

The New York 1937 Act was effective on May 19, 1937 
and the revised Federal Act on June 3, 1937. The first 
Federal Order with co-operative payments was that for 
New York (Order No. 27) issued August 5, 1938, effective 
September 1, 1938. This was suspended in 1939 and was 
reinstated effective July 1, 1939. The amendment to the 
New York Act (§258-m 11, clarifying the provisions as to 
co-operative payments) was effective on June 7, 1939. It 
reads in part as follows: 

“Any marketing agreement or order of the Com¬ 
missioner may provide (a) for payments to co-opera¬ 
tive associations of producers in cases where the 
Commissioner finds that such associations are actually 
rendering such marketing services to producers under 
contract with them, or are rendering services in the 
control and disposition of surplus for the benefit of 
the market; • • V’ 




CONCLUSION 


The judgment below should be reversed. 

Respectfully submitted, 

Seward A. Miller 
Frank B. Lent 
New- York City 
Attorneys for Intervenor, 
Dairymen’s League Cooperative 
Association, Inc. 

Wm. E. Leahy 
Wm. J. Hughes, Jr. 

Bowen Building 
Washington, D. C. 

Of Counsel 




43 


APPENDIX I 

Extract from Bulletin DM-6, issued August 1938 by 
United States Department of Agriculture, Agricul¬ 
tural Adjustment Administration, Division of Market¬ 
ing and Marketing Agreements, Dairy Section, in Ex¬ 
planation of the Federal-State Marketing Plan Con¬ 
tained in Order No. 27 for the New York Metropoli¬ 
tan Marketing Area in Connection with the Presenta¬ 
tion of such Order for Referendum of Producers, and 
after Public Hearings Thereon, (pp. 10 and 11). 

“PAYMENTS OUT OF POOL 

Payments for services by cooperatives are to be made 
to those cooperative associations which have been deter¬ 
mined by the Secretary of Agriculture as having their 
entire activities under the control of their members and as 
being able to render service to producers as a whole by 
facilitating the delivery of milk to persons at the point 
where it may be used in the highest possible class and by 
making available to handlers in need of milk, an adequate 
supply. These payments would go to producers’ cooper¬ 
atives which exercise control over milk and route milk 
into the channels of utilization which net the highest re¬ 
turns to all producers. 

Under the order, any cooperative association of pro¬ 
ducers may apply to the Secretary of Agriculture for de¬ 
termination as to its qualifications to receive the cooper¬ 
ative service payment. If the determination is made in 
favor of the cooperative, the service payment is to be re¬ 
ceived by the cooperative until it has been disqualified by 
the Secretary for failure to exercise the authority and to 
perform the functions upon which the determination was 
made. 

These payments are to be made at only one of the fol¬ 
lowing rates on net pooled milk dealt with by a coopera¬ 
tive: 



44 


One cent per hundredweight of net pooled milk to 
a cooperative which caused the milk of its members 
to be delivered to a handler’s plant and on which the 
handler made reports to the market administrator and 
paid producers as required under the order; 

Two and a half cents per hundredweight of net 
pooled milk to a cooperative which has collected pay¬ 
ments for milk delivered to the plant of a handler 
by its members and which has met its obligations 
under the order; and 

Five cents per hundredweight of net pooled milk 
to a cooperative which operates plants, is able to take 
care of all the milk of all its members, and is willing 
and able to take care of milk from producers who are 
not members.’’ 


APPENDIX H 

Extract from Compilation of Department of Agriculture. 


“Section 4 of S. 3426 

The third proposed amendment to section 8c (5) of the 
act, being section 4 of S. 3426, adds new language to the 
present law which makes clear and definite the authority 
to provide in a marketing order regulating milk and its 
products for the payment of cooperative and market serv¬ 
ice differentials. 

The proposed amendment while embraced in a single 
paragraph expresses two independent authorizations — one 
designated (i) and the other designated (ii). 

That part designated (i) refers to payments to cooper¬ 
atives for rendering services to the market. Such pay¬ 
ments are authorized in the present law by virtue both 
of section 8c (5) (B) and section 8c (7), the former being 
quoted hereinbefore and section 8c (7) providing: 

‘(7) In the case of the agricultural commodities and 
the products thereof specified in subsection (2) orders 
shall contain one or more of the following terms and con¬ 
ditions : 



45 


‘(D) Incidental to, and not inconsistent with, the terms 
and conditions in subsections (5) (6) and (7) and neces¬ 
sary to effectuate the other provisions of such order.’ 

Reason .—In order to make definite and certain the Sec¬ 
retary’s authority in this regard and to settle the question 
that insufficient standards are spelled out in the act to 
guide the Secretary, it is regarded as essential that the 
law be amended in the respects contemplated by section 4 
of S. 3426. 

The market services for which these payments may be 
made to a qualifying cooperative are clearly set forth in 
the brief of the United States Government in the case of 
United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., et al. (307 
U. S. 533, 59 S. Ct. 993, pp. 158 et seq.), which may be para¬ 
phrased as follows: 

(1) Service performed in supplying class I milk to the 
marketing area in times of short supply; 

(2) Service performed in the utilization of milk in times 
of long supply in such manner as to insure the greatest 
possible return to producers; 

(3) Service performed by the maintenance throughout 
the year of facilities for handling the seasonable surplus 
even though these facilities can be employed only during 
the flush season; 

(4) Service performed for the market by the employ¬ 
ment of measures during flush periods of production to 
secure the utilization in fluid form of milk near to the 
market, and the utilization in manufactured form of milk 
produced at the edge of the milkshed, thus reducing trans¬ 
portation charges which must be shared by all producers; 

(5) Miscellaneous services performed for the benefit 
of the entire market with respect to weights, tests, market 
outlets, etc. 

The amendment proposed in section 4 of S. 3426, namely, 
part (i) thereof, will make it clear and certain that the 
Secretary of Agriculture in his discretion has full power 
to fix differentials in favor of cooperative associations 
which are rendering these or similar services and which 



46 


services tend to effectuate the public policy of the Market¬ 
ing Agreement Act. By the amendment the Secretary will 
have authority to fit such payments appropriately to the 
value of the service rendered. 

It is to be noted further that as a prerequisite to re¬ 
ceiving any such payment, the cooperative must be bona 
fide and under the exclusive control of its member-pro¬ 
ducers. Furthermore, it must be in full compliance with 
all provisions of the marketing order which govern it.” 

NOTE There was a further statement on page 27 
that the payments would be made out of the settle¬ 
ment fund under the provisions of 8c(5)(C) of the 
Act. 


APPENDIX III 

Statement of Mr. E. W. Gaumnitz, Director, Division 
of Marketing and Marketing Agreements, Agricultural 
Adjustment Administration, Department of Agricul¬ 
ture, at Hearing before Senate Committee on April 
1-4, 1940 (pp. 52-53) relating to Sec. 4 of S. 3426. 

“Section 4, which also appears on page 4 of the com¬ 
pilation, amending section 8c(5) (C), recognizes and now 
provides specifically that the power to fix minimum prices 
to handlers and the manner of making payments to pro¬ 
ducers can include in the total segregation from the total 
value of milk, as fixed by an order, a sum to provide a 
reasonable compensation to bona fide producer-owned and 
producer-controlled associations for services which they 
may render to the entire market, and from which all pro¬ 
ducers derive benefits. The services for which compen¬ 
sation may be paid are to be specified by the Secretary, and 
thus permit an adaptation of such requirements to a par¬ 
ticular marketing program and to the character of market¬ 
ing facilities that may be found in one market, as con¬ 
trasted with those in another. Such payments and their 
continued receipt by a qualified cooperative are condi- 




47 


tioned upon compliance with the orders applicable to such 
receiving association, and thus channels producer money 
only to cooperative marketing organizations which are 
marketing milk in a manner that will support the entire 
marketing program. 

This amendment also specifically provides for another 
kind of payment, not limited to cooperative associations for 
the disposition of surplus fluid milk in flush seasons, and 
in the maintenance and release of available supplies in 
short seasons, in such a manner as will maintain maximum 
stability supply and prices in the market. 

In general, the two provisions contained in section 4 
supplement each other and together provide a way whereby 
all producers who enjoy the benefits of such marketing 
also carry a reasonable and proportionate share of the 
burden involved. Specific standards are included as a 
guide for carrying out its provisions. 

Senator Schwellenbach. Now, what, in your experience, 
causes you to want that proposal? Why would that pro¬ 
vision be desirable? 

Mr. Gaumnitz. Again it is primarily a matter of at¬ 
tempting to avoid controversy and litigation. Provisions 
similar to that carried in this section have been included 
in certain of the milk orders, specifically that for New 
York, which was before the Supreme Court, and on which 
the Supreme Court ruled favorably. However, it is one 
of those provisions that are controversial in character, 
and it was thought that the inclusion of a specific author¬ 
ity might eliminate, in whole or in part, additional litiga¬ 
tion with respect to the enforcement of marketing agree¬ 
ments and orders. 

Senator Schwellenbach. You mean that the amount 
allowed as reasonable is controversial, not the principle 
that you should be entitled to fix the reasonable compen¬ 
sation? 

Mr. Gaumnitz. Well, the first question is as to the prin¬ 
ciple, and it would appear that the court has pretty well 
passed on the principle, although it still is a controversial 



48 


point. The question of reasonableness has not come up 
directly.” 


APPENDIX IV 

Extract trom Report of Committee on Agriculture 
and Forestry, Accompanying S.3426 (Report No. 1719, 
67th Cong. 3d Sess.) pp. 7-8, as to Section 4 of the Bill. 

“Section 4 of the amending bill amends section 8c(5)(C) 
of the act by providing specifically for the segregation, from 
the total value of milk as fixed by the order, of sums to 
provide reasonable compensation for two distinct kinds of 
marketing services as indicated in the provisions desig¬ 
nated as (i) aud (ii). This authority is considered as being 
involved in the power to fix minimum prices to handlers 
and the manner of making payments to producers already 
contained in the act. Hence, the purpose of section 4 is to 
establish more explicit standards by which the Secretary 
shall be guided in providing for such compensation. Both 
types of services are definitely associated with the proper 
functioning of an order program and the effectuation of 
the policy of the act. 

The services for which compensation is authorized by 
the provision designated by (i) are of the type regarded 
as essential in carrying out the method of payment to pro¬ 
ducers authorized by paragraphs (B) (ii) and (C) of 
subsection (5) of section 8c under the method of pricing 
milk to handlers provided in paragraph (A) of the same 
sub-section. Authorization of such compensation to be 
paid out of any pool or fund established under paragraph 
(C) of subsection (5) involves the fundamental principle 
that such services be those which are identifiable as benefit¬ 
ing all producers with a reasonable degree of equality as 
distinguished from services, the benefits of which are lim¬ 
ited primarily to members of a particular cooperative 
association. Illustrations of these types of marketing 
services are suggested in the amendment itself, but the 


49 


Secretary is authorized to specify others which may con¬ 
form to these general principles when necessary to achieve 
the same marketing results under circumstances peculiar 
to different markets. Because of the nature of such serv¬ 
ices, compensation with respect thereto is limited to bona 
fide cooperative marketing associations, all of whose oper¬ 
ations are under the full control of milk producers. 

The services for which compensation is authorized by 
the provision designated by (ii) are in addition to and in 
no way a duplication of the services for which compensa¬ 
tion is authorized under (i). The payments authorized by 
(ii) are similar to location differentials now authorized, 
having to do with the movement and handling of milk, 
and are available to any plant operator, irrespective of 
whether or not such operator is also a cooperative asso¬ 
ciation. This type of allowance is designed to cover costs 
involved in the movement of milk from or to processing 
plants when marketing conditions are such as to necessi¬ 
tate such movement in order to maximize returns to all 
producers. 

Eligibility of an association or operator to receive pay¬ 
ments authorized by (i) and (ii) from a pool or fund as 
established by an order is further conditioned upon com¬ 
pliance with the applicable provisions of the order. These 
two provisions supplement each other and together pro¬ 
vide a way whereby all producers who enjoy the benefits 
of such marketing services also carry a reasonable and 
proportionate share of the burden involved.” 







Lr O-OP ERAT 

ive 















INDEX 


Page 


Jurisdictional Statement . 1 

Statement of the Case. 3 

Statute and Order Involved. 6 

Statement of Points. 6 

Summary of Argument. 6 

Argument: 


I. The payments to co-operative associations of producers 
for market-wide services are authorized by section 8c (5) 
and section 8c(7) (D) of the statute providing that, in 
addition to the enumerated terms, conditions, and adjust¬ 
ments which may be included in a marketing order, such 
additional provisions may be included as are incidental 
to, and not inconsistent with, the enumerated terms and 
conditions in section 8c(5), and necessary to effectuate 
the other provisions of the order. 9 

A. The qualified co-operative associations of pro¬ 

ducers, in engaging in certain activities, includ¬ 
ing the providing of facilities or other outlets 
for surplus milk and in various other respects 
advancing the interests of producers in general, 
are performing market-wide services, under the 
order, for which payment should be made from 
the producer-settlement fund under the order... 12 

B. The provisions for payments to co-operatives for 

market-wide services are not inconsistent with 
section 8c(5) of the Act. 25 

C. The statute’s terms, purposes, background, and 

history indicate that section 8c(7) (D) of the Act 
is to be given its plain meaning and to include 
payments to co-operative associations for mar¬ 
ket-wide services whenever there is warrant in 
the hearing record . 27 

D. The scope of judicial review is limited to the in¬ 

quiry as to whether substantial evidence in the 
hearing record, on which the Secretary’s order 
is based, supports the Secretary’s action. There 
being no question that substantial evidence sup¬ 
ports the Secretary’s findings that the order 
provisions for payments to co-operatives are in¬ 
cidental and necessary under section 8c(7) (D) 
of the Act, and not inconsistent with section 
8a(5), and inasmuch as the appellees failed to 
place the entire hearing record before the Court, 
the appellees’ attack upon the provisions of the 


order must fail. 36 

II. The challenged provisions are plainly authorized by the 
Act, and the Government’s motion for summary judg¬ 
ment should have been sustained. 40 


(i) 












II 


Page 

Conclusion. 42 

Appendix: 

Relevant sections of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement 

Act of 1937 . 43 

Relevant sections of the Boston milk marketing order. 46 

CITATIONS 

Cases: 

American Power d Light Co. v. Securities and Exchange Com¬ 
mission, 329 U. S. 90. 35 

American Sugar Refining Co. v. Louisiana, 179 U. S. 89. 31 

Armour dr Co. v. Wantock, 323 U. S. 126. 34 

Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Anderson (C.A. 8), 157 F. 2d 87. . . . 28, 34 
Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Jones (D.C. E.D. Mo.), 61 F. Supp. 

209 . 34,36 

Borden Co. v. Borella, 325 U. S. 679 . 34 

Brushaber v. Union Pacific Railroad Co., 240 U. S. 1. 31 

Cardillo v. Liberty Mutual Insurance Co., 330 U. S. 469 . 38 

Chicago Board of Trade v. Olsen, 262 U. S. 1. 31 

Crane v. Commissioner, 331 U. S. 1. 32 

Crull v. Wickard (C.A. 6), 137 F. 2d 406 . 36 

Dairymens League Co-operative Association, Inc. v. Brannan 

(C.A. 2), 173 F. 2d 57. 7 

Dobson v. Commissioner, 320 U. S. 489 . 38 

Flint v. Stone Tracy Co., 220 U. S. 107. 31 

Gemsco, Inc. v. Walling, 324 U. S. 244 . 33, 34 

George Moore Ice Cream Co. v. Rose, 289 U. S. 373. 29 

Gray v. Powell, 314 U. S. 402 . 37, 38 

Green Valley Creamery v. United States (C.A. 1), 10S F. 2d 

342 . 26 

Hood dr Sons v. DuMond, 336 U. S. 525. 28 

H. P. Hood dr Sons v. United States, 307 U. S. 588.4,8,13 

Hughes v. Securities and Exchange Commission (C.A. D.C.) 

174 F. 2d 969. 37 

In re Marketing Association of Fort Wayne, Inc. (D.C. D. 

Ind.), 8 F. 2d 626. 31 

Interstate Commerce Commission v. Jersey City, 322 U. S. 

503 . 37 

Interstate Commerce Commission v. Union Pacific R. Co., 

222 U. S. 541. 37 

Jones v. Liberty Glass Co., 332 U. S. 524. 32 

Liberty Warehouse Co. v. Burley Tobacco Growers Co-operative 

Marketing Association, 276 U. S. 71. 31 

National Labor Relations Board v. Hearst Publications, 322 

U. S. Ill .11,38,39 

National Labor Relations Board v. Nevada Copper Corp., 316 

U. S. 105. 38 

National Labor Relations Board v. Southern Bell T. dr T. Co., 


Nebbia v. New York, 291 U. S. 502. 37 

































Ill 

Cases—Continued 

Page 

New York State Guernsey Breeders’ Co-operative Association 

v. Wickard, (C.A. 2), 141 F. 2d 805. 30 

Parker v. Motor Boat Sales, Inc., 314 U. S. 244.. 38 

People v. Teuscher, 248 N. Y. 454 . 31 

Porter v. Murray (C.A. 1), 156 F. 2d 781. 33 

Puerto Rico v. Shell Co., 302 U. S. 253. 12 

Queensboro Farms Products Inc. v. Wickard (C.A. 2), 137 F. 

2d 969 . 6,9,10,11,36,40 

Rochester Telephone Corp. v. United States, 307 U. S. 125. ... 38 

Securities and Exchange Commission v. C. M. Joiner Leasing 

Corp., 320 U. S. 344 . 32 

Shapiro v. United States, 335 U. S. 1. 36 

Shields v. Utah Idaho Central R. Co., 305 U. S. 177. 37 

Sioux Tribe of Indians v. United States, 316 U. S. 317. 33 

South Chicago Coal & Dock Co. v. Bassett, 309 U. S. 251. 11, 38 

Stark v. Wickard, 78 App. D. C. 44,136 F. 2d 786. 2 

Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288. 2, 3,4, 7,15,16 

Sunshine Anthracite Coal Co. v. Adkins, 310 U. S. 381. 35 

Swayne & Hoyt v. United States, 300 U. S. 297. 38 

Thompson v. Consolidated Gas Utilities Corp., 300 U. S. 55... 9,40 

Titusville Dairy Products Co. v. Brannan (C.A. 3), 176 F. 2d 

332 . 36 

United States v. American Trucking Association, 310 U. S. 534. 11 

United States v. Dotterweich, 320 U. S. 277. 28 

United States v. Ridgeland Creamery Co. (D.C. W.D. Wise.), 

47 F. Supp. 145. 34 

United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 

533 . 7, 8 , 9,10,12,30,31,40 

United States v. Ruzicka, 329 U. S. 287. 37 

Vcrmilya-Brown Co. v. Connell, 335 U. S. 377. 11 

Victor Mfg. & Gasket Co. v. National Labor Relations Board 

(C.A. 7), 174 F. 2d 867. 37 

Waddington Milk Co. v. Wickard (C.A.2), 140 F. 2d 97. 36 

Wallace v. Hudson-Duncan <& Co. (C.A. 9), 98 F. 2d 985 . 9,40 

Wawa Dairy Farms v. Wickard (C.A. 3), 149 F. 2d 860. 36,40 

Wetmiller Dairy & Farm Products, Inc. v. Wickard (C.A. 2), 

149 F. 2d 330. 36 

Statutes and Orders: 

Act of July 3, 1948, c. 827, 62 Stat. 1258, 7 U.S.C. Supp. II, 

672. 22 

Agricutural Marketing Act, 1931, 21 and 22 -Geo. 5 c. 42, $ 6 

(Vol. 1 , Halsbury’s Statutes of England, 2 d ed., p. 243)_ 35 

Agricultural Marketing Act of June 15, 1929, 46 Stat. 18, 12 

U.S.C. 1141 . 30 

Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 

246, 7 U.S.C. 601 et seq. 2 ,6 

Section 2 ( 1 ) . ’9 

Section 8 c(3) . 20 

Section 8 c (4) . 20 

Section 8 c (5) . 4,7,9,10,11,15, 23,25, 26,27,28,29,36,39 



































IV 

Statutes and Orders—Continued _ 

Page 

Section 8c(7)(D) . 4,7,10,11,26,27,28,29,36 

Section Sc(8) . 10 

Section 8c(9) . 5,10 

Section Sc(B) . 28,29 

Section 8c (15) . 36 

Section 8c(18) . 9 

Section 10(b)(1) . 30 

Boston Milk Order. 1, 3,5, 6,18, 21,23,25,26 

Capper-Volstead Act, 42 Stat. 388, 7 U.S.C. 291. 30 

Clayton Act, 3S Stat. 730,15 U.S.C. 17. 30 

Commodity Exchange Act, 49 Stat. 1491, 7 U.S.C. 10a. 31 

Louisville Milk Order. 34 

New York Milk Order.5,21,25,34 

Public Utility Holding Co. Act of 1935 . 35 

Reorganization Act of 1945, 5 U.S.C. I33y et seq . 5 

Robinson-Patman Act, c. 592, 49 Stat. 1528, 15 U.S.C. 13b.. 30 

St. Louis Milk Order . 34 

Miscellaneous: 

Black, The Dairy Industry and the AAA (The Brookings In¬ 
stitution, 1935) . 14 

Cassels, A Study of Fluid Milk Prices (Harvard Economic 

Studies, 1937) . 13 

Cooperative Marketing of Dairy Products (Farm Credit Ad¬ 
ministration, by Harry C. Trelogan and French H. Hyre, 

June 1939) . 22 

S6 Cong. Rec. 12256 . 33 

86 Cong. Rec. 12258-12259 . 33 

86 Cong. Rec. 12266. 33 

Federal Rules of Civil Procedure. 5 

Gaumnitz and Reed, Some Problems Involved in Establishing 

Milk Prices (U. S. Department of Agriculture, 1937). 13 

Hearings, Subcommittee of Senate Committee on Agriculture 

and Forestry on S. 3426, 76th Cong., 3d Sess.. 33 

Lininger, Dairy Products under the Agricultural Adjustment 

Act (The Brookings Institution, Pamphlet Series No. 13).... 14 

Milk Report of Reorganization Commission for Great Britain 
(Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries, Economic Series 

No. 44) . 35 

New England Dairyman.22,23 

Nourse, (Director of the Institute of Economics, Brookings In¬ 
stitution), American Cooperation, 1934 . 30 

Nourse, Marketing Agreements under the AAA (Brookings In¬ 
stitution, 1935) . 13 

Nourse, The Legal Status of Agricultural Cooperation (The In¬ 
stitute of Economics, 1927). 31 

Our Milk. 23 

Report of the Federal Trade Commission on the Distribution 
and Sale of Milk and Milk Products (74th Cong., 2d Sess., 

H. Doc. No. 501). 13 

Report of the Ontario Royal Commission on Milk, 1947. 14 

S. 3426, 76th Cong., 3d Sess. 32 

Seasonality of Milk Deliveries in the Boston Milkshed (U. S. 
Department of Agriculture, Bureau of Agricultural Eco¬ 
nomics, June 1949). 13 






































V 

Miscellaneous—Continued 

Page 


Sommer, Market Milk (2d ed. 1946). 13 

The Dairy News. 23 

The Louisville Fall-Premium Plan for Seasonal Milk Pricing 
(Kentucky Agricultural Experiment Station, University of 

Kentucky) . 34 

The Maine Milk Producer . 23 









®mteb States Court of Appeals 

FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT 

October Term, 1949 


Nos. 10,365 and 10,366 


Charles F. Brannan, Secretary of Agriculture, 

APPELLANT 


v. 

Delbert 0. Stark, A. F. Stratton, A. R. Denton, 
G. Stebbins, and F. Walsh, appellees 


Dairymen’s League Co-operative Association, Inc., 

APPELLANT 

V. 

Delbert 0. Stark, A. F. Stratton, A. R. Denton, 
G. Stebbins, and F. Walsh, appellees 


ON APPEAL FROM A JUDGMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 
DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA 


BRIEF FOR THE SECRETARY OF AGRICULTURE, 

APPELLANT 


JURISDICTIONAL STATEMENT 


< 


This action was instituted as a class action by five dairy 
farmers to enjoin the Secretary of Agriculture from mak¬ 
ing certain payments to co-operative associations of pro¬ 
ducers pursuant to the Boston milk marketing order (7 






o 


CFR, 1941 Supp., 904.1 et seq.)> effective under tlie Agri¬ 
cultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (Act of June 
3, 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 246, 7 U. S. C. 601 et seq.). The 
complaint alleges that the payments to the co-operative 
associations of producers are not authorized by the stat¬ 
ute. The suit was dismissed by the District Court of the 
United States on the ground that the Act vests no legal 
cause of action in milk producers, as contradistinguished 
from milk handlers who are regulated by the order, and 
its judgment was affirmed by the United States Court of 
Appeals for the District of Columbia. Stark v. Wickard, 
78 App. D. C. 44, 136 F. 2d 786. That decision, however, 
was reversed in Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288, by the hold¬ 
ing that dairy farmers, as plaintiffs, “have legal standing 
to object to illegal provisions of the Order,” and the Dis¬ 
trict Court was directed in the remanding of the case to con¬ 
sider, in the judicial examination of the complaint, “the 
soundness of the allegations made by the petitioners in their 
complaint,” and “whether the statutory authority given the 
Secretary is a valid answer to the petitioners’ contention.” 

The District Court -was of the opinion (Joint App. 142- 
150) in the reconsideration of the case that the statute does 
not depute authority to the Secretary to include in a milk 
marketing order any of the challenged provisions for pay¬ 
ments for market-wide services rendered by the co-opera¬ 
tive associations, and the court entered judgment (Joint 
App. 154-155) on April 25, 1949, enjoining the Secretary 
from making further payments, under the Boston milk 
marketing order, to co-operative associations of producers. 
The effectiveness of the judgment was stayed by the Dis¬ 
trict Court (Joint App. 156-157) on condition that all such 
payments should be held in escrow pending the final dis¬ 
position of the case on appeal. 

The opinion of the court below is officially reported in 
82 F. Supp. 614, and the opinion also appears in the Joint 
Appendix, pp. 142-150. The notice of appeal was filed 
(Joint App. 157) on June 21, 1949, by the defendant, the 
Secretary of Agriculture. The intervenor-defendant, the 
Dairymen’s League Co-operative Association, Inc., filed 




3 


notice of appeal (Joint App. 157-158) on June 21, 1949. 
The jurisdiction of this Court is invoked under Title 28, 
United States Code, 1291 and 1294. 

STATEMENT OF THE CASE 

The complaint alleges (Joint App. 6) that there is no 
statutory authorization for the provisions in the Boston 
milk order providing for payments to co-operative associa¬ 
tions of producers for services rendered to the market as 
a whole, and that such provisions in the order are, therefore, 
‘ 4 without legal authority, and are unlawful and void. ” It is 
further alleged (Joint App. 2) in the complaint that the 
appellees’ milk is distributed in the Boston marketing area, 
as defined in the order, and that in the operation of the 
market-wide pool all producers receive a uniform blended 
price per hundredweight for milk based upon the market¬ 
wide utilization of the milk, and it is averred that the uni¬ 
form blended price is illegally decreased by virtue of the 
deduction, from the pool, of the payments made to the co¬ 
operative associations of producers. The complaint asks 
that the provisions in the order for payments to co-opera¬ 
tive associations of producers be declared illegal and void, 
and that such payments under those provisions be enjoined. 

The only question resolved by Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 
288, is that the dairy farmers—even though not regulated 
under the order—who instituted this action have such a legal 
interest in the producer-settlement fund as entitles them to 
challenge the action of the Secretary in directing the dis¬ 
bursements, from such fund, to co-operative associations of 
producers. In deciding that the persons who instituted this 
action have such an interest as justifies judicial considera¬ 
tion, the Court stated (321 U. S. 311), in reversing and 
remanding the case, that: 

“It hardly need be added that we have not considered 
the soundness of the allegations made by the petitioners 
in their complaint. The trial court is free to consider 
whether the statutory authority given the Secretary 
is a valid answer to the petitioners’ contention. We 
merely determine the petitioners have shown a right 
to a judicial examination of their complaint.” 




4 


The appellees assert that the only issue is one of “statu¬ 
tory power to make the deduction required by Order, § 904.9, 
under the authority of §8c(7)(D) of the Act.” Stark v. 
Wkkard, 321U. S. 28S, 307. The Act provides that milk mar¬ 
keting: orders may contain one or more of the terms and con¬ 
ditions expressly set forth in § 8c(5) of the Act and, in addi¬ 
tion to the enumerated terms and conditions of § 8c(5), an 
order may contain such provisions as are “incidental to, 
and not inconsistent with, the terms and conditions speci¬ 
fied in subsections (5), (6), and (7) [of § 8c of the Act] and 
necessary to effectuate the other provisions of such order.” 
Because the Congress could not foresee every contingency 
in this field in which “the economy of the industry is so 
eccentric that economic controls have been found at once 
necessary and difficult,” 1 it did not set forth in the Act 
minute formularies which leave no option and permit no 
latitude. On the contrary, the “terms of the Order are 
largely matters of administrative discretion” and the tech¬ 
nical details “are left to the Secretary and his aides.” 
Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288, 310. 

The provisions of the order 8 for payments to co-operative 
associations of producers for services rendered to the mar¬ 
ket as a whole were included by amendment to the order, 
effective August 1, 1941. These provisions in the amended 
order are based on evidence adduced at a public hearing, 
and the findings of fact -were made (7 CFR, 1941 Supp., 
904.0) by the Secretary that (1) the payments to co-opera¬ 
tive associations of producers for market-wide services are 
incidental to, and not inconsistent with, the terms and con¬ 
ditions in § 8c(5) of the Act, and such payments to the co¬ 
operative associations of producers are necessary to effec- 


1 The quotation is from Hood & Sons v. DuMond, 336 U.S. 525, 
529. 

2 Section 904.9 of the order, as amended on August 1, 1941, con¬ 
tains the provisions (7 CFR, 1941 Supp., 904.9), asserted to be 
illegal. These provisions in the order were amended, in various 
respects, on August 1, 1947, and the section number was changed 
to 904.10 (7 CFR, 1947 Supp., 904.10). The plaintiffs’ complaint 
was amended (Joint App. 132) so as to apply to the order as 
amended on August 1, 1947. 






5 


tuate the other provisions of the amended order; (2) the 
minimum prices provided for by the amended order are 
necessary to effectuate the declared policy of the Act, i.e., 
to insure, in the public interest, a sufficient quantity of pure 
and wholesome milk; and (3) the amended order, and all 
of its terms and conditions, will tend to effectuate the de¬ 
clared policy of the Act. These findings by the Secretary, 
on the basis of the hearing record, were approved by the 
President in accordance with §8c(9) of the Act. 3 The 
appellees do not assert any lack of substantial evidence 
to support the foregoing findings by the Secretary, but the 
appellees contend that, as a matter of statutory interpre¬ 
tation, the Act does not authorize the challenged provisions 
in the order. 

The New York milk order (7 CFR, 927.1 et seq.) contains 
provisions for payments to co-operative associations of 
producers, for market-wide services; and the Dairymen’s 
League Co-operative Association, Inc., a qualified co-opera¬ 
tive for payments under the New York milk order, inter¬ 
vened as a party defendant. The application for interven¬ 
tion was approved by the District Court under Rule 24(b) 
of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure (28 U.S.C. follow¬ 
ing 723c) on the basis that the claim of the Dairymen’s 
League Co-operative Association, Inc., for payments under 
the New York milk order is “in common” with the issue 
involved in this case as to the statutory authority for 
similar payments under the Boston milk order. The in- 
tervenor-defendant appealed from the judgment of the 
District Court, and asserts that its interests are adversely 
affected by the judgment of the lower court that there is 
no statutory authorization for payments to co-operative 
associations of producers for market-wide services. 


3 Acting pursuant to the Reorganization Act of 1945 (5 U.S.C. 
133y et seq.), the President abolished, by § 102 of the “Reorganiza¬ 
tion Plan No. 1 of 1947,” the function of the President with respect 
to approving determinations of the Secretary of Agriculture in con¬ 
nection with the issuance of marketing orders under the Act. 93 
Cong. Rec. 4488-89 (1947), 4510-12 (1947); 12 F.R. 4535; and 
5 U.S.C. Supp. II 133y-16. The Reorganization Plan No. 1 of 
1947 became effective on July 1, 1947. 







6 


STATUTE AND ORDER INVOLVED 

The relevant parts of the Agricultural Marketing Agree¬ 
ment Act of 1937 (Act of June 3, 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 246, 
7 TJ.S.C. 601 et seq.), and the Boston milk marketing order, 
as amended (6 F.R. 3762, 5481, 7 CFR, 1941 Supp., 904.0 
et seq.; and 12 F. R. 4921, 7 CFR, 1947 Supp., 904.0 et seq.), 
are set forth in the Appendix to this brief, infra, pp. 43-49. 

STATEMENT OF POINTS 

I 

The provisions in the Boston milk marketing order, as 
amended, providing for payments to the co-operative asso¬ 
ciations of producers for market-wide services are within 
the statutory authority conferred on the Secretary of Agri¬ 
culture by the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 
1937, as amended (7 U.S.C. 601 et seq.). The District Court 
erred, therefore, in adjudging that those provisions of the 
amended order are not authorized by the Act, and the 
District Court was in error in enjoining the Secretary from 
making the payments to the co-operative associations of 
producers as provided for in the amended order. 

II 

Inasmuch as the provisions in the Boston milk marketing 
order, as amended, for payments to the co-operative asso¬ 
ciations of producers, for market-wide services, are au¬ 
thorized by the Act, the motion for summary judgment 
filed by this appellant (Joint App. 58-59) on October 2, 
1946, should have been sustained by the District Court. 
The action of the District Court in denying the motion for 
summary judgment was reversible error. 

SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT 

The “exquisitely complicated” 4 nature of milk market- 

4 The quotation is from Queensboro Farms Products, Inc., v. 
Wickard (C.A. 2), 137 F. 2d 969, 974, with respect to the com¬ 
plexities of milk marketing in general, and in particular in the 
New York metropolitan milk marketing area. 



7 


ing and tlie “monstrous difficulty” 5 of regulation are such 
that the Congress provided that, in addition to specified 
terms and conditions to be included in a milk marketing 
order and “adjustments” which may be made, such auxil¬ 
iary provisions may be included under § 8c(5) and §8c(7) 
(D) of the Act as are “incidental . . . and necessary to 
effectuate the other provisions of such order.” United 
States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 575. 
In issuing the amended Boston milk order, effective August 
1, 1941, the Secretary made findings of fact (7 CFR, 1941 
Supp., 904.0), on the basis of the evidence in the hearing 
record, that the payments to the co-operative associations 
of producers for market-wide services are incidental and 
necessary, under §8c(7)(D) of the Act, to effectuate the 
provisions in the order included under §8c(5) of the Act, 
and that such payments to co-operatives for market-wide 
services are not inconsistent with § 8c(5) of the Act. The 
appellees do not contend that there is an absence of sub¬ 
stantial evidence to support the findings by the Secretary, 
but it is asserted by the appellees that the statutory author¬ 
ization for “incidental . . . and necessary” provisions 
cannot, as a matter of law, include provisions for payments 
to co-operatives for market-wide services. 

The provisions in a milk order “are largely matters of 
administrative discretion.” Stark v. Wickard, 321 U S. 
288, 310. There is nothing in the statute’s background, 
terms, or purposes to indicate that the term “incidental 
. . . and necessary” is to be regarded as a term of art 
having, as a matter of law, a definite and circumscribed 
meaning so that its application, irrespective of the facts, is 
to be ascertained in vacuo. 6 This statutory authorization 
is to be applied in the light of the mischief to be corrected 
and the economic goal to be attained, and a provision found 
by the Secretary, on the basis of the hearing record, to be 

5 The quotation is from Dairymen’s League Co-operative Asso¬ 
ciation, Inc. v. Brannan (C.A. 2), 173 F. 2d 57, 66, the opinion of 
the Court being by Judge Learned Hand. 

6 The statute expressly prohibits certain provisions, but does not 
prohibit payments to co-operatives for market-wide services. 
Exceptions set forth in detail are not to be enlarged by implication. 


8 


incidental and necessary is to be tested by whether the find¬ 
ings have warrant in the evidence. The findings by the 
Secretary and the challenged provisions in the amended 
order are within the plain provisions of the Act. It must be 
assumed that Congress evidently meant what the plain 
terms of the Act ordinarily convey. 7 

The co-operatives who qualify for these payments per¬ 
form market-wide services in connection with the handling 
of surplus milk, market-wide services in connection with 
the formulation of data and representation of the interests 
of producers in general at public hearings, from time to 
time, and in the dissemination of information and data to 
producers necessary to effectuate the classification, pooling, 
and pricing provisions of the order. 

The problem of disposing of surplus milk has plagued the 
Boston and New York markets for a long period. Nebbia 
v. New York, 291 IT. S. 502, 517-518; United States v. Rock 
Royal Co-op. Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 549-550; and II. P. Hood 
<£ Sons v. United States, 307 U. S., 588, 593. The production 
of milk is much greater in the spring and summer than 
during the remainder of the year; the number of cows 
necessary to produce enough fluid milk to meet the require¬ 
ments during the period of short supply will produce a 
much greater amount in the spring and early summer 
months. The milk order does not require a handler to accept 
any or all milk offered to him by a producer. The blended 
price which a handler must pay under the order is, there¬ 
fore, inapplicable to surplus milk for which a producer 
can find no handler who is willing to purchase. 

The co-operatives who qualify for payments under the 
order perform market-wide services in finding outlets for 
this surplus milk—outlets on the fluid milk market, if pos¬ 
sible, and at least outlets in manufacturing channels. All 
producers—and not merely members of the co-operatives— 
are benefited by the market-wide services by the co-opera- 

7 Moreover, the Act requires the Secretary to accord such en¬ 
couragement to co-operatives as will be consonant with the liberal 
policy towards co-operatives set forth in many Congressional enact¬ 
ments. 


9 


tives with respect to surplus milk, and also relative to the 
various other respects in which the co-operatives advance 
the interests of the producers in general. The Secretary 
maintains close supervision with respect to these services, 
and the payments to a co-operative are suspended whenever 
there is “reason to believe” that the co-operative is no 
longer performing the market-wide services. 7 CFR, 904.10 
and 927.9(f). 

Assuming, arguendo, that the appellees can and do attack 
the provisions in the order as not being based on substantial 
evidence, the attack must fail because the hearing record 
on which the present provisions are based is not before 
this Court. The order was again amended with respect to 
payments to co-operatives on August 1,1947, and no part of 
that hearing record was ever introduced in this litigation by 
the appellees. The predicative findings of the Secretary, in 
issuing these amendments effective August 1, 1947, carry 
a presumption of the existence of a state of facts justifying 
the action. United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 
307 U. S. 533, 567-568; Thompson v. Consolidated Gas 
Utilities Corp., 300 U. S. 55, 69; Wallace v. Hudson-Duncan 
& Co. (C.A. 9), 98 F. 2d 985; and Queensboro Farms Prod¬ 
ucts, Inc. v. Wickard (C.A. 2), 137 F. 2d 969, 977-981. 

ARGUMENT 

I. The Payments to Co-operative Associations of Pro¬ 
ducers for Market-Wide Services are Authorized by Sec¬ 
tion 8c(5) and Section 8c(7) (D) of the Statute Providing 
That, in Addition to the Enumerated Terms, Conditions, 
and Adjustments Which may be Included in a Marketing 
Order, Such Additional Provisions may be Included as are 
Incidental to, and not Inconsistent with, the Enumerated 
Terms and Conditions in Section 8c(5), and Necessary to 
Effectuate the Other Provisions of the Order. 

The Act plainly sets forth the purpose of milk orders, 8 

8 Sections 2(1) and 8c (18) of the Act (7 U.S.C. 602(1) and 
608c(18)). 


10 


prescribes the manner in which the orders may be issued, 9 
and outlines the terms and provisions which the orders may 
contain. 10 The order may contain the terms or conditions 
enumerated in § 8c(5) of the Act and, in addition, such pro¬ 
visions under § Sc (7) (D) of the Act as are “incidental to, 
and not inconsistent with, the terms and conditions speci¬ 
fied in subsections (5), (6), and (7) [of § 8c of the Act] 
and necessary to effectuate the other provisions of such 
order.” Congress did not attempt to limit the regulatory 
provisions to terms of classification, pooling, and pricing 
set forth in § 8c(5) of the Act; the statutory provision in 
§ 8c(5) is plain that orders may contain one or more of 
the terms and conditions in § 8c(5), “and, except as pro¬ 
vided in subsection (7) [of § 8c], no others.” (Emphasis 
supplied.) It was stated in United States v. Rock Royal 
Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 576, in reviewing the pro¬ 
visions of the Act and sustaining its constitutionality, that 
§ 8c(7)(D) of the Act permits the inclusion of “pro¬ 
visions auxiliary to those definitely specified.” 

The Congress was not seeking to solve the harassing eco¬ 
nomic problems, with which the statute deals, by solutions 
rigidly limited to a code of specifics. The Act authorizes 
“incidental . . . and necessary” provisions to effectuate 
the terms and conditions expressly mentioned in the Act. 11 
The “exquisitely complicated” field of milk marketing 
(Queensboro Farms Products, Inc. v. Wickard (C.A. 2), 
137 F. 2d 969, 974) is such that to counteract the virulent 
effects of disorderly marketing the “incidental . . . and 
necessary” authorization calls for a continuous process of 
application; it cannot be reduced to formula, for relevancy 
and adequacy are matters variable in relation to the diver¬ 
gent, unstable, and mutable situations within the purposes 
and scope of the program. “The background and legisla- 


9 Sections 8c(3), 8c(4), 8c(5), 8c(8), and 8c(9) of the Act 
(7 U.S.C. 608c(3), 608c(4), 608c(5), 608c(8), and 608c(9)). 

10 Sections 8c (5) and 8c (7) of the Act (7 U.S.C. 608c (5) and 
608c (7)). 

11 The provisions in the order for payments to co-operatives are 
“not inconsistent” with the terms and provisions in the Act. This is 
dealt with, infra, pp. 25-27. 





11 


tive history of this legislation [the Act nnder which the milk 
orders are effective] leave no donbt that Congress gave 
the Secretary broad discretion inj its administration.” 
Queensboro Farms Products, Inc. v. Wickard (C.A. 2), 
137 F. 2d 969, 977. 

In issuing the amended order, effective August 1, 1941, 
the Secretary made findings of fact (7 CFR, 1941 Supp., 
904.0), on the basis of the evidence in the hearing record, 
that the payments to the co-operative associations of pro¬ 
ducers for market-wide services are incidental and neces¬ 
sary, under § 8c(7) (D) of the Act, to effectuate the provi¬ 
sions in the order included under § 8c(5) of the Act, and 
that such payments to co-operatives are not inconsistent 
with § 8c(5) of the Act. The appellees do not question 
the adequacy of the evidence to support the findings, but 
contend that, as a matter of law, the statutory term “inci¬ 
dental . . . and necessary” cannot be said to include 
market-wide services by co-operatives even though such 
market-wide services are found to be necessary to effectuate 
the other provisions of the order. 

The various terms in the amended order reveal and give 
confirmation as to the necessity, in the light of the purpose 
of the regulatory program, for including the provisions for 
payments to the co-operative associations of producers who 
perform services for the market as a whole. These pro¬ 
visions, limned against the whole background of the statute 
and the order, are plainly authorized by § 8c(7) (D) of the 
Act as “incidental to . . and necessary to effectuate 

the other provisions of such order.” The words of the 
Act are to be construed if reasonably possible to effectuate 
the intent of the lawmakers; and this meaning in particular 
instances is to be arrived at not only by a consideration of 
the words themselves, but by considering, as well, the pur¬ 
poses of the law, and the circumstances under which the 
words were employed. V ermilya^Brown Co. v. Cormell, 
335 IT. S. 377, rehearing denied, 336 U. S. 928; National 
Labor Relations Board v. Hearst Publications, 322 U. S. 
Ill; United States v. American Trucking Association, 310 
U. S. 534; South Chicago Coal & Bock Co. v. Bassett, 309 




12 


U. S. 251; and Puerto Rico v. Shell Co., 302 U. S. 253, 258. 
The economic objective of these regulatory programs was 
modified, in some respects, by the Act of July 3, 1948, c. 
827, 62 Stat. 1258, but the Congress provided in title III, 
§ 302(e), of the enactment (7 U. S. C. Supp. II, 672) that all 
programs presently in effect ‘‘shall continue in effect with¬ 
out the necessity for any amendatory action. ” 

A. The Qualified Co-operative Associations of Producers, 
in Engaging in Certain Activities, Including the Providing 
of Facilities or Other Outlets for Surplus Milk and in Vari¬ 
ous Other Respects Advancing the Interests of Producers 
in General, are Performing Market-Wide Services, Under 
the Order, for Which Payment Should he Made From the 
Producer-Settlement Fund Under the Order. 

‘‘The fluid milk industry is affected by factors of insta¬ 
bility peculiar to itself which call for special methods of 
control.” Nehbia v. New York, 291 U. S. 502, 517. The 
economic imbalances in the production and marketing of 
milk, even under normal conditions, prevent the adjustment 
of supply and demand. United States v. Rock Royal Co-o-p. 
Inc.. 307 U. S. 533,549. In view of the well-known variations 
in demand and in the volume of milk produced—particularly 
the seasonal oscillation in production—it is necessary, in 
order to avoid shortages during some of the time, that the 
supply should at all times exceed the minimum requirements 
of the fluid milk market. The reserve or surplus must be 
maintained to insure a sufficient and regular supply to the 
fluid milk market. 

Whatever the minimum safety margin may be, it would 
not be possible to maintain that minimum in winter without 
exceeding it in summer, owing to the seasonal variation in 
milk production. The biological nature of milk production 
is such that it cannot be controlled with precision; and milk, 
in view of its highly perishable and bulky nature, cannot be 
satisfactorily stored for long periods of time. The number 
of cows necessary to produce enough fluid milk to meet the 
requirements of the market during the fall and winter 
months will produce a much greater amount in the spring 


13 


and early summer months. 1 " “Under the best practicable 
adjustment of supply to demand, the [fluid milk] industry 
must carry a surplus of about 20 percent.” Nebbia v. New 
York, 291 U. S. 502, 517. This is sometimes referred to as 
the “necessary surplus.” 13 

The surplus milk produced for, but not disposed of on, 
the fluid milk market is generally marketed—if marketed 
at all—in manufacturing outlets for milk products in com¬ 
petition with milk produced elsewhere for manufacturing 
purposes. To produce and handle milk in accordance with 
the elaborate precautions (Sommer, Market Milk, (2d ed. 
1946) pp. 116-121 and 211-243) required by the health au¬ 
thorities for milk marketed as fluid milk is far more expen¬ 
sive than to produce milk just for manufacturing purposes. 
Surplus milk produced for the fluid milk market but dis¬ 
posed of to manufacturers must be sold at a price sub¬ 
stantially lower than the price received on the fluid milk 
market. 14 In the absence of regulation, the pressure of 

12 The production of milk in June in the Boston milkshed is 
almost twice as much as in November (Joint App. 229). The 
demand for fluid milk, however, is relatively stable throughout the 
year. Handlers usually keep on hand, or at least available, a supply 
slightly in excess of their average daily demand for fluid milk. 
This operating reserve may be distinguished from the far greater 
surplus which arises from the large seasonal increases in produc¬ 
tion, in the spring and early summer. 

13 The surplus milk problem exists in the Boston market the 
same as in the New York market. H. P. Hood & Sons v. United 
States, 307 U.S. 588, 593. See, also, Report of the Federal Trade 
Commission on the Distribution and Sale of Milk and Milk 
Products (74th Cong., 2d Sess., H. Doc. No. 501), pp. 13-44; 
Nourse, Marketing Agreements under the AAA (Brookings Institu¬ 
tion, 1935), pp. 200-201; and Gaumnitz and Reed, Some Problems 
Involved in Establishing Milk Prices (U.S. Department of Agricul¬ 
ture, 1937), pp. 53 et seq.; and Cassel’s, A Study of Fluid Milk 
Prices (Harvard Economic Studies, 1937), pp. 242 et seq. In 
recent years the Boston market has not been able to obtain enough 
milk, from its milkshed, to meet the market demands for fluid 
milk during the fall and winter months, although on “an annual 
basis, even in recent years, the supply from the Boston milkshed 
has greatly exceeded the requirements for fluid milk." Seasonality 
of Milk Deliveries in the Boston Milkshed (U.S. Department of 
Agriculture, Bureau of Agricultural Economics, June 1949) p. 2. 

14 “It costs him [the producer] as much to produce and transport 
[the surplus milk] as the milk he sells at the standard fluid milk 


14 


unrestricted competition tends to compel those engaged in 
handling milk to attempt to shift the burden of the surplus 
to others. A producer or handler with surplus milk may be 
constrained to make desperate efforts to dispose of it on 
the fluid milk market, or at least find some outlet for it, and 
this precipitates retaliatory efforts by competitors with the 
result that eventually disorderly marketing conditions re¬ 
dound to the detriment of producers, handlers, and con¬ 
sumers. The disorderly marketing of milk, with the in¬ 
evitable disintegrating effect on the dairy industry, results 
eventually in a lowering of quality in milk because of en¬ 
forced relaxation of safeguards in the production and 
distribution of milk, a curtailment in the supply of milk, 
and interruptions due to strikes and disorders. This has 
been the history of milk marketing in the Boston and New 
York milksheds; the problem of the surplus has plagued 
these two milk markets for decades, 15 and has been the 
subject of many public investigations. Black, The Dairy 
Industry and the AAA (The Brookings Institution, 1935), 

pp. 182-210. 

There is complete homogeneity of the entire supply of 
milk approved by the health authorities for fluid use as milk 
in the Boston marketing area. That situation applies like¬ 
wise with respect to milk approved for the New York 
metropolitan marketing area. This homogeneity of the milk 
supply for the respective marketing areas is illustrated by 
the hypothetical example: If the total approved supply, 
for one of these marketing areas, were received at a single 
plant and the fluid milk market in that area utilized only 
75 percent of the total approved supply, there could be no 
discernible basis for selecting one producer’s milk rather 

price, and if the market for fluid milk cannot absorb it he must 
sell it, if possible, as surplus milk. If he is not able to sell it, it is 
a dead loss apart from the use to which he can put it on his own 
farm. If he can sell it, he sells it at what is known as the secondary 
price -which . . . is . . . less than the prevailing price for fluid 
milk consumed as such.” Report of the Ontario Royal Commission 
on Milk, 1947 (by the Honorable Dalton C. Wells, a Justice of the 
Supreme Court of Ontario), p. 60. 

15 Lininger, Dairy Products Under the Agricultural Adjustment 
Act (the Brookings Institution, Pamphlet Series No. 13) p. 3 et seq. 





15 


than that of another for shipment to the fluid milk market, 
nor could one producer’s milk be distinguished from that of 
another. All of the milk in that case would be equally avail¬ 
able for the fluid milk market. The burden of the surplus 
should, therefore, be shared equitably by all of the pro¬ 
ducers. “It is apparent that serious inequities as among 
producers might arise if the prices each received depended 
upon the use the handler might make of his milk; accord¬ 
ingly, §8c(5)(B) [of the Act] authorizes provision to be 
made for the payment to producers of a uniform price for 
the milk delivered irrespective of the use to which the milk 
is put by the individual handler.” Stark v. Wickard, 321 
U. S. 288, 295. If the milk is priced to producers on a use 
basis, tbe price should be the weighted average of the prices 
in the classes in which the milk is utilized. If all producers 
do not share equitably in the marketing of the milk, pro¬ 
ducers discriminated against seek to establish a different 
or direct outlet to fluid milk users, and by that method, the 
history of each market shows, disorderly marketing condi¬ 
tions are eventually engendered. 

In a market with as high a degree of specialization as 
exists in the Boston or New York milksheds, all of the 
approved milk is not, of course, physically intermingled, 
but all of it is equally available for sale in the respective 
marketing area just the same as if the total supply were 
physically intermingled. In view of these circumstances, 
facilities must be provided for handling the inevitable 
excess in periods of surplus production, and for an 
equitable sharing of the burden of the surplus. The usual 
classification, pooling, and pricing provisions of the order 
are not enough, in the Boston and New York markets, to 
bring about the necessary equitable sharing of the surplus 
load to effectuate the purpose of the Act. 

The milk order does not require a handler to accept 
delivery of milk from a producer or, if the milk is accepted, 
to utilize the milk for disposition as fluid milk, i.e., in the 
higher classification. In some instances, it may be more 
profitable to the handler, although not more profitable to 
the producers, to utilize the milk in a lower class. The 


16 


handlers are free to accept or decline to receive milk; and 
the handlers are free to dispose of the milk as they see fit. 
The classification, pooling, and pricing provisions—without 
the incidentally necessary provisions for market-wide 
services by cooperative associations of producers—relate 
to the calculus of price. As explained in Stark v. Wickard, 
321 U. S. 288, 296-301, the Boston milk order provides for 
a market-wide pool which is an equalization method under 
which the individual producer is paid for the milk which 
he sells to a handler in accordance with the use made of all 
the milk sold in the market, rather than the use made of 
the individual producer’s milk or the use made of all the 
milk of a particular handler. The blended or uniform 
price is computed, in the case of this market-wide equaliza¬ 
tion pool, by multiplying the amount of all the milk in the 
market disposed of for fluid or Class I purposes by the 
Class I price, and the amount of all the milk disposed of in 
the market for manufacturing or Class II purposes by the 
Class II price, and then by dividing the sum of the two 
resulting figures—less certain deductions, including pay¬ 
ments to the co-operatives ,a —by the total amount of milk 
disposed of in the market. Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288, 
298-301. In effect, the order treats the milk of all pro¬ 
ducers, engaged in the production of milk for the Boston 
marketing area, as if commingled in a common supply reser¬ 
voir from which the various handlers can purchase milk and 
pay the producers the minimum blended price fixed by the 
order. 

The blended price under the order has no relevancy or 
application to surplus milk for which a producer can find 
no market; the order is applicable only to milk that handlers 
are willing to accept from producers. Moreover, the 
blended price is a lower price or a higher price depending 
on the market-wide utilization of the milk by the handlers, 
i.e., whether it is utilized on the fluid milk market at the 
Class I price or on the manufacturing market at the Class II 
price. These significant circumstances are factors that, 


16 The order requires several deductions for purposes admittedly 
authorized by the Act. Stark v. Wickard, 321 U.S. 288, 300. 






17 


unless otherwise dealt with in the order, hinder or prevent 
the effectuation of the classification, pooling, and pricing 
provisions in the order. These facts are such that if 
orderly marketing is to be established so as to attain the 
economic objective of the Act—i.e., to insure, in the public 
interest, an adequate supply of pure and wholesome milk— 
incidental or auxiliary provisions must be adopted whereby 
the highest possible utilization may be had for the surplus. 
If this classified price scheme is to be properly effective, it 
is necessary to include some provisions for distributing 
among the producers the advantages of the fluid milk 
market and the burden of the surplus. In Nebbia v. New 
York, 291 U. S. 502, 517-518, the Court described this basis 
for necessitous action as follows: 

“A satisfactory stabilization of prices for fluid milk 
requires that the burden of surplus milk be shared 
equally by all producers and all distributors in the 
milkshed. ’ ’ 

The fixing of minimum prices to be paid by handlers for 
milk, classified according to its use, is designed as the 
primary method of regulation under the Act. Certain 
market-wide responsibilities are, however, performed by 
co-operative associations of producers, in the Boston and 
Xew York milksheds, in order to effectuate the classifica¬ 
tion, pricing, and pooling provisions in the Order; an outlet 
must be available, in as high use classification as possible, 
for the surplus milk in order to enable each producer to 
realize the proper benefit of the prices fixed by the order. 

The compelling fact is that the producers, in the normal 
production area, whose milk is required for the fluid milk 
market in the season of short production constitute the 
permanent productive force for the market; and when these 
producers have surplus milk, it must be utilized in some 
outlet if the annual supply is to be maintained. Manufac¬ 
turing facilities must be available to handle the milk 
that cannot be utilized on the fluid milk market. Those 
co-operatives who provide the plants and facilities often 
must assume considerable expense, and in addition assume 
costs measured in the expenditure of personal skill and 




18 


managerial capacity which are out of the ordinary (Joint 
App. 179 and 184). The plants and the manufacturing 
facilities required to handle the surplus milk are not or¬ 
dinarily required, or at least not fully required, at other 
times of the year. The plants must be maintained as 
stand-by facilities, and as such they represent outlays of 
capital, by those who undertake to provide such facilities, 
in excess of the capital costs of other operators of the same 
size, measured by the volume of their fluid milk business, 
who assume no part of the burden of surplus disposal (Joint 
App. 213-214). In addition, operating costs under such 
conditions are often greater than normal. Those co-oper¬ 
atives who provide these surplus processing facilities, 
having converted the surplus into various manufactured 
dairy products, must seek wholesale or retail markets for 
the products, often through business channels and in dis¬ 
tant localities with which they, in their ordinary capacity 
as fluid milk processors or distributors in a local market, 
are not familiar. To the extent that these manufactured 
dairy products in the Boston market are the by-products of 
seasonal aberrations in the supply, they are produced, and 
must be put on the market, in odd lots; and those selling 
such products are at the competitive disadvantage of having 
no established brand names and of being unable to contract 
with wholesalers or jobbers to deliver continuous supplies. 
As the result lower prices must be accepted. 

The co-operative associations of producers that operate 
milk plants have provided facilities which have made pos¬ 
sible the maintenance of supplies for the market under con¬ 
ditions of seasonally fluctuating production. In 1939 the 
co-operatives having milk plants handled 46 percent of all 
the milk regulated by the Boston milk order, but the co¬ 
operatives had 57.2 percent of the surplus milk (Joint App. 
228 and 230a). The co-operative associations handle a 
proportionately larger share of surplus than proprietary 
handlers, and in doing so the co-operative associations make 
a major contribution to the solution of the problem of 
handling the surplus. 

The physical receipt of surplus milk at a plant of a regu- 



19 


lated handler who will, under the marketing order, pay the 
blended price for such milk is, of course, an element in 
milk marketing. But particularly in the Boston market, 
the use in which milk is finally disposed of by handlers, 
after receipt from producers, is also of great importance 
to certain types of handlers and to producers as a whole, 
whose blended price directly reflects the use of milk. In the 
Boston market, milk handlers are specialized as to the 
range of handling operations they perform. Some pro¬ 
prietary handlers are strictly distributors of bottled fluid 
milk—buying all their requirements from plants of co¬ 
operative associations, and processing no surplus milk. 
Others in varying degree, in relation to their fluid sales 
requirements, buy direct from producers but not up to the 
point where they would have any surplus in their plants. 
A few proprietary handlers, in addition to distributing 
fluid milk, engage in processing part of the market’s 
surplus. 

There are two significant aspects of the specialization of 
the proprietary handlers who depend upon co-operatives 
for all or part of their fluid milk requirements. These pro¬ 
prietary handlers have in effect transferred all or sub¬ 
stantially all of the necessary surplus handling operations 
to the co-operatives. A plant manufacturing milk products 
of the types in which the surplus is disposed, in the Boston 
market, must handle a relatively large volume of milk if 
the various products are to be processed at low unit costs 
and the plant is to operate efficiently. The smaller pro¬ 
prietary handlers have recognized the consequences of that 
fact for their businesses. Because of the small sizes of 
their respective fluid milk operations, the relatively small 
volumes of surplus milk which they would have to manu¬ 
facture if they secured all supplies of milk from producers 
and handled the total production of their suppliers, includ¬ 
ing the heavy spring production of such producers, would 
result in relatively inefficient manufacturing operations. 
Therefore, these handlers have avoided or reduced ineffi¬ 
ciencies in their own operations by minimizing their direct 
receipts from producers, and they rely upon purchases from 



20 


the co-operatives to make up the balance of their require¬ 
ments in the months of low production. 

The co-operatives in undertaking to supply proprietary 
handlers with fluid milk, on demand, channel milk from the 
initial receipt from producers to the ultimate use, in the 
highest value class, in the form which makes it available to 
consumers as fluid milk. The co-operatives 1 function in 
this respect tends to maximize blended prices to producers, 
because fluid distributors are able to obtain milk on short 
notice to meet maximum Class I demands and to meet the 
demand of consumers for an adequate supply of fluid milk, 
thereby making it possible for the smaller proprietary han¬ 
dlers to do business in the market primarily as fluid milk 
distributors. The co-operative associations serve as fluid 
milk suppliers for many of these proprietary handlers. 
The sales of Class I milk in 1939 by co-operatives to pro¬ 
prietary handlers ranged from 6,039,000 pounds to 55 han¬ 
dlers in June to 12,853,000 pounds to 104 handlers in No¬ 
vember (Joint App. 230a). The volume of milk sold by 
co-operatives as Class I milk in June to proprietary han¬ 
dlers was approximately 13 percent of the total utilization 
of Class I milk in the market for the month, and in Novem¬ 
ber the co-operatives sales of Class I milk approximated 
28 percent of the total utilization of Class I milk for that 
month. 17 

Price fixing under Federal orders is not static; it is a 
continuing process. The design of a successful plan of regu¬ 
lation to be incorporated in a milk marketing order and 


17 These percentages are derived by dividing the figures for total 
sales of Class I milk sold by co-operatives to proprietary handlers 
in June and November, shown in Government Exhibit No. 6, 
Joint App. p. 230a, by the figures for total Class I utilization in 
the market for the respective months, reflected in Government 
Exhibit No. 2, Table 30, Joint App. p. 228. The figures for total 
Class I utilization in the market for June and November are shown 
in Exhibit No. 2, Table 30, as average daily Class I utilization as 
reported by handlers representing 95 percent of all regulated milk 
in the market. To obtain figures for total Class I utilization for 
these months for 100 percent of the market, the daily average figures 
are divided by .95 and multiplied by the number of days in the 
respective months. 






21 


tlie process of effective administration and amendment of 
its regulatory provisions require constant attention to an 
extensive and complicated set of conditions. There should 
be some mechanism or method for discovering, organizing, 
and analyzing the facts relative to current marketing con¬ 
ditions, for determining their significance, and for propos¬ 
ing either the initiation of market regulation by means of 
an order or necessary changes in an existing order. Co¬ 
operative associations, including those whose activities con¬ 
sist mainly of bargaining for milk sales, i. e., bargaining 
co-operatives, as well as the associations which operate milk 
plants, i. e., operating co-operatives, have given such con¬ 
tinuous attention to all types of marketing conditions falling 
within the scope of the Boston marketing order that this 
phase of their activity has, in practical fact, been of much 
significance in the effectuation of the regulatory process 
(Joint App. pp. 218-219). Some co-operatives in the market 
employ trained economists to ascertain and represent pro¬ 
ducers’ interests. Their analytical work has furnished the 
impetus in many instances to the calling of public hearings 
to consider amendments to the order. Their expert testi¬ 
mony in the public hearings enables the establishment of a 
factual basis for adjusting prices and other regulatory pro¬ 
visions of the order to changing market conditions. It is 
not to be expected that individual producers, with their 
limited means, would be able to represent themselves or to 
present competent evidence as to what action should be 
taken under regulation in the best interest of all producers. 
These co-operatives that receive payments for market-wide 
services are constantly engaged in formulating data and in 
otherwise preparing for public hearings that are held from 
time to time on proposed amendments to the Boston and 
New York milk orders. 

It is impossible for an individual dairy farmer—prac¬ 
tically all of whose time must be devoted to production— 
to study market conditions so as to market his milk in a 
scientific manner. It is impossible for the average dairy 
farmer of small means to obtain the advantages obtainable 



22 


by large organizations. It is impossible for an individual 
dairy farmer to build a manufacturing plant or to provide 
adequate outlets for the surplus milk in the market so as to 
achieve maximum returns to producers. It is impossible 
for an individual dairy farmer to increase market demand 
by substantial advertising. But above all, it is impossible 
for an individual dairy farmer to effectuate an equitable 
sharing of the burden of surplus milk—so essential if the 
classification, pooling, and pricing provisions of the Boston 
order are to effectuate the declared purpose of the Act. To 
do these things, which the individual dairy farmer cannot 
do, requires a Federal order in the Boston market providing 
for the payment of a uniform blended price to producers, 
on the basis of market-wide utilization of milk, and the per¬ 
formance of these market-wide services by the co-operatives. 

The co-operatives “are able to keep in touch with the 
supply situation and divert milk to its most economical uses 
better than any other market agency.” Cooperative Market¬ 
ing of Dairy Products (Farm Credit Administration, by 
Harry C. Trelogan and French M. Hyre, June 1939) p. 8. 
In addition to positive action to inform and shape the course 
of regulation in the market, the co-operative associations 
constantly carry on informational activities which have the 
effects of interpreting the regulation to producers and of 
educating producers with regard to market conditions. 
Educational meetings are held at which non-members, as 
well as members, may attend. Radio programs 18 are regu¬ 
larly maintained by some of the co-operatives and in this 
manner non-members, as well as members, are kept in¬ 
formed as to current market conditions. Some co-opera¬ 
tives publish and issue to their members periodicals which, 
while circulation is mainly among members of these co¬ 
operatives. frequently contain articles urging and assisting 


18 E.g., New England Dairyman (September 1941), Vol. 25, 
No. 9, p. 6; New England Dairyman (August 1945), Vol. 29, 
No. 8, pp. 1 and 3, and (September 1945), Vol. 29, No. 9, pp. 1 
and 16; New England Dairyman (November 1945), Vol. 29, No. 11, 

p. 2. 






23 


producers to market milk so that their collective efforts will 
benefit all interests in the market. 10 

There is another significant respect in which the pay¬ 
ments to the co-operatives, for market-wide services, relate 
in a proximate manner to the class prices established by the 
order. In fixing the class prices authorized by §8c(5) of 
the Act, consideration must be given to the possibilities for 
disposition of surplus milk. The class prices are determined 
at least to some extent by the prospective returns from sur¬ 
plus milk. If the surplus milk is to be dumped for lack of 
any outlet, the prices under the order may be substantially 
different from the prices in the event of an outlet for the 
surplus milk. To hold that the provisions in the order en¬ 
couraging the disposition of surplus milk to the best ad¬ 
vantage of all producers, in the market, are not auxiliary 
to the fixing of class prices is to fail to recognize compelling 
and irrefutable facts. 

In determining the Class II price, which applies to surplus 
milk, the costs of handling such milk and the net returns to 
handlers from its sale must be considered, if adequate 
market outlets for surplus are to be maintained under the 
order. On August 1,1941, the date on which the co-operative 
payment provisions were adopted in the order, a number 
of other amendments were also made effective, including 
a change in that element of the Class II price which gives 
consideration to the costs of handling Class II, or surplus, 
milk. The change in the Class II price provision was made in 
specific contemplation of one of the effects which was antici¬ 
pated to flow from the co-operative payment provisions 
(Joint App. 89). The price change and the effect of the co- 


19 E.G., each issue of the New England Dairyman, The Dairy- 
News, The Maine Milk Producer, and Our Milk contains a special 
article analyzing the blended price, under the Boston milk order, 
for the preceding month. These publications regularly contain 
articles dealing with the production and utilization of milk in the 
Boston milkshed, the factors determining the blended price, outlets 
for surplus milk, current economic conditions, and from time to 
time proposed amendments to the Boston milk order. 




24 


operative payment provisions were designed to provide 
properly for an outlet for all surplus milk at a proper price. 
The co-operative payment provisions were directly related 
to the class price provisions. In effect, the co-operative 
payment provisions, in this respect, constitute a part of 
the pricing of milk. 

Careful supervision is required by the order with regard 
to these payments to co-operatives. The payments are not 
made to all co-operatives, but only to those who perform 
the market-wide services. Each co-operative that receives 
these payments is required to submit to the Market Ad¬ 
ministrator reports, from time to time, with respect to its 
“performance in meeting the requirements set forth as the 
basis for such payments.” 7 CFR, 904.10(c) and 
927.9(f). The Market Administrator maintains close super¬ 
vision over the co-operatives with regard to these payments, 
and whenever “there is reason to believe” that a co¬ 
operative is no longer performing the market-wide services, 
the payments are suspended and held in reserve by the 
Market Administrator until the Secretary has, after notice 
and opportunity for a hearing, ruled as to the performance 
of the co-operative. 7 CFR, 904.10(d) and 927.9(f). 

All co-operatives who receive payments do not receive 
payments at the same rate. Under the New York order, for 
example, a payment is made to bargaining co-operatives— 
the rate depending on the services performed; and a higher 
payment is made to operating co-operatives “who have 
sufficient plant capacity to receive all the milk of producers 
who are members and to be willing and able to receive milk 
from producers not members.” 7 CFR, 927.9(f). Any 
co-operative who receives any payment must, under the 
order, arrange for and supply “in times of short supply, 
('lass I milk to the marketing area,” and secure “utilization 
of milk, in times of long supply, in a manner to assure the 
greatest possible returns to all producers.” 7 CFR, 
927.9(f). Other requirements also must be met before a 
co-operative is entitled to receive these payments for 







25 


market-wide services. Under the Boston order, as well as 
under the New York order, a co-operative can receive no 
payment unless its application has been submitted to the 
Secretary, and the Secretary has made a determination that 
the respective co-operative is performing the market-wide 
services and is, therefore, entitled to the payments. 7 CFR, 
904.10(a) and 927.9(f). 

The rates of payment to co-operatives under the Boston 
order were modified by amendments effective August 1, 
1947 (12 F. R. 4921; 7 CFR, 1947 Supp., 927.9). The hear¬ 
ing record on which those amendments were issued is not 
a part of the record in this case. The co-operative pay¬ 
ment provisions were originally included in the Boston or¬ 
der on August 1, 1941, and the hearing record on which 
those amendments w'ere based is included in the record in 
this case. But the order provisions now in effect are based 
on a hearing record which the appellee did not introduce 
in the record in this case. 20 

B. Tho Provisions for Payments to Co-operatives for 
Market-Wide Services are not Inconsistent with Section 
Sc(5) of the Act. 

The lower court was of the opinion (Joint App. 146) that 
the payments to the co-operatives, for market-wide serv¬ 
ices, are an “adjustment” that is inconsistent with the re¬ 
quirement in §8c(5) of the Act that, under a market-wide 
pool, the payments to all producers and associations of 
producers delivering milk to all handlers shall be at a uni¬ 
form price for all milk so delivered subject only to the 
adjustments specified in §8c(5) of the Act. The lower 
court’s opinion states (Joint App. 146) that $8c(5) of the 
Act enumerates “the exact types of provisions that may be 
contained in a marketing order,” and specifies the “adjust¬ 
ments that the Secretary may make in computing the price 


20 The scope of judicial review under these circumstances is dis¬ 
cussed, infra , pp. 36-40. 





26 


to be paid to producers,” and that under the terms of 
§ 8c(5) of the Act a milk order may contain “no others.” 

The lower court failed to take into consideration another 
provision in the Act. The limitations in § 8c(5) to the terms 
and conditions enumerated therein “and no others” is 
qualified by the prior statement that “except as provided in 
subsection (7) [of § 8c of the Act],” a milk order is limited 
to one or more of the terms and conditions set forth in 
§Sc(5). The provision for payments to co-operatives, for 
market-wide services, is based on § 8c(7) (D) of the Act, and 
therefore by the specific language of § 8c(5) an adjustment 
or provision under the “incidental . . . and necessary” 
authorization is not required to be found in § Sc(5), and if it 
is an adjustment at all it may be in addition to those in 
$ Sc(5). 

Assuming, arguendo, that the statutory exception for 
provisions under § Sc(7)(D) is not applicable so as to per¬ 
mit an adjustment in addition to those adjustments specified 
in § Sc(5) of the Act, it is clear that these payments to co¬ 
operatives for market-wide services are not inconsistent 
with §8c(3). They are not adjustments to the “uni¬ 
form prices” required by the Act to be paid to producers. 
Cf. Green Valley Creamery v. United States (C. A. 1), 
10S F. 2d 342, 345. Section 8c(5)(A) of the Act 
requires that prices to handlers shall be “uniform as to all 
handlers” subject to certain enumerated adjustments. 
There is no question that the Boston order provides for 
prices uniform as to all handlers. Section 8c(5)(B) of the 
Act merely provides that prices paid by the same handler 
under subparagraph (i) or by handlers under sub-para¬ 
graph (ii) shall be uniform to all producers and associations 
of producers for “all milk delivered by them.” There is 
no requirement in the statute that the uniform prices to 
producers must reflect the total utilization of milk received 
by handlers and priced under the order. There is no re¬ 
quirement in the statute that the total sums paid by each 
handler equal the total sums paid to producers or associa¬ 
tions of producers under the order. There is no require¬ 
ment in the statute that the total amount paid to producers 



27 


or associations of producers must equal the value of the 
milk purchased by handlers at the prices specified in the 
order. The payments to the co-operative associations, for 
market-wide services, are deducted before the computation 
of the blended price, and the making of the co-operative 
payments does not alter or interfere with the requirement 
in the Act for “uniform prices” for all milk delivered by 
producers. 

Assuming, arguendo, that the payments to co-operatives 
for market-wide services are adjustments to the “uniform 
price” and can be justified only if expressly authorized by 
§ 8c(5) of the Act, the provisions in question are within the 
authorization in § 8c(5) (B) to make “a further adjustment, 
equitably to apportion the total value of milk purchased by 
any handler, or by all handlers, among producers and asso¬ 
ciations of producers, on the basis of their marketings of 
milk during a representative period of time.” The market¬ 
wide services by co-operatives are necessary “equitably to 
apportion” the total value of milk among all producers. 

The proprietary handler is not expected to perform these 
market-wide services, since from the nature of its business 
a proprietary handler is interested only in the spread be¬ 
tween the purchase price and the sale price of milk. A co¬ 
operative association performing market-wide services is, 
however, interested in securing the highest possible return 
for producers. A co-operative association must account 
to the pool at the class prices, and the co-operative pay¬ 
ments compensate, at least in part, the association for the 
losses incurred in performing the market-wide services; and 
such payments are necessary in order ‘ ‘ equitably to appor¬ 
tion” the total value of milk among all producers. 

C. The Statute’s Terms, Purposes, Background , and His¬ 
tory Indicate that Section 8c(7)(D) of the Act is to be Given 
Its Plain Meaning and to Include Payments to Co-operative 
Associations for Market-Wide Services Whenever There is 
Warrant in the Hearing Record. 

If one goes beyond the plain meaning that the “inci¬ 
dental . . . and necessary” authorization in § 8c(7) (D) 





26 


to be paid to producers,” and that under the terms of 
§ Sc(5) of the Act a milk order may contain “no others.” 

The lower court failed to take into consideration another 
provision in the Act. The limitations in § 8c(5) to the terms 
and conditions enumerated therein “and no others” is 
qualified by the prior statement that “except as provided in 
subsection (7) [of § 8c of the Act],” a milk order is limited 
to one or more of the terms and conditions set forth in 
§ Sc(5). The provision for payments to co-operatives, for 
market-wide services, is based on § 8c(7) (D) of the Act, and 
therefore by the specific language of § 8c(5) an adjustment 
or provision under the “incidental . . . and necessary” 
authorization is not required to be found in § Sc(5), and if it 
is an adjustment at all it may be in addition to those in 
§ 8c(5). 

Assuming, arguendo, that the statutory exception for 
provisions under § 8c(7)(D) is not applicable so as to per¬ 
mit an adjustment in addition to those adjustments specified 
in § Sc(5) of the Act, it is clear that these payments to co¬ 
operatives for market-wide services are not inconsistent 
with. $ 8c(5). They are not adjustments to the “uni¬ 
form prices” required by the Act to be paid to producers. 
Cf. Green Valley Creamery v. United States (C. A. 1), 
10S F. 2d 342, 345. Section 8c(5)(A) of the Act 
requires that prices to handlers shall be “uniform as to all 
handlers” subject to certain enumerated adjustments. 
There is no question that the Boston order provides for 
prices uniform as to all handlers. Section 8c(5)(B) of the 
Act merely provides that prices paid by the same handler 
under subparagraph (i) or by handlers under sub-para¬ 
graph (ii) shall be uniform to all producers and associations 
of producers for “all milk delivered by them.” There is 
no requirement in the statute that the uniform prices to 
producers must reflect the total utilization of milk received 
by handlers and priced under the order. There is no re¬ 
quirement in the statute that the total sums paid by each 
handler equal the total sums paid to producers or associa¬ 
tions of producers under the order. There is no require¬ 
ment in the statute that the total amount paid to producers 





27 


or associations of producers must equal the value of the 
milk purchased by handlers at the prices specified in the 
order. The payments to the co-operative associations, for 
market-wide services, are deducted before the computation 
of the blended price, and the making of the co-operative 
payments does not alter or interfere with the requirement 
in the Act for “uniform prices” for all milk delivered by 
producers. 

Assuming, arguendo, that the payments to co-operatives 
for market-wide services are adjustments to the “uniform 
price” and can be justified only if expressly authorized by 
§ 8c(5) of the Act, the provisions in question are within the 
authorization in § 8c(5) (B) to make “a further adjustment, 
equitably to apportion the total value of milk purchased by 
any handler, or by all handlers, among producers and asso¬ 
ciations of producers, on the basis of their marketings of 
milk during a representative period of time.” The market- 
wide services by co-operatives are necessary “equitably to 
apportion” the total value of milk among all producers. 

The proprietary handler is not expected to perform these 
market-wide services, since from the nature of its business 
a proprietary handler is interested only in the spread be¬ 
tween the purchase price and the sale price of milk. A co¬ 
operative association performing market-wide services is, 
however, interested in securing the highest possible return 
for producers. A co-operative association must account 
to the pool at the class prices, and the co-operative pay¬ 
ments compensate, at least in part, the association for the 
losses incurred in performing the market-wide services; and 
such payments are necessary in order “equitably to appor¬ 
tion” the total value of milk among all producers. 

C. The Statute 7 s Terms , Purposes , Background , and His¬ 
tory Indicate that Section 8c(7) (D) of the Act is to be Given 
Its Plain Meaning and to Include Payments to Co-operative 
Associations for Market-Wide Services Whenever There is 
Warrant in the Hearing Record. 

If one goes beyond the plain meaning that the “inci¬ 
dental . . . and necessary” authorization in § 8c(7) (D) 





28 


spontaneously yields, all other relevant considerations con¬ 
firm what the text of the Act expressly authorizes. 

Regard for the purposes of a remedial statute “should 
infuse construction of the legislation if it is to be treated 
as a working instrument of Government and not merely as a 
collection of English words.” United States v. Dotter - 
wcich, 320 U. S. 277, 280. The very words “incidental . . . 
and necessary,” with the purposes of the statute in mind, 
import breadth of coverage, and admonish against a con¬ 
stringent construction which would result in the legislation 
affording only a partial solution to the economic evils 
dealt with by the Act. 

The Act expressly prohibits the inclusion of certain pro¬ 
visions in milk orders, and those are the only exceptions 
or provisions which, as a matter of law, cannot be included 
under the “incidental and necessary” authorization in 
§ Sc (7)(D) of the Act even if the hearing record should 
contain evidence of their desirability. It is provided that 
“no order applicable to milk and its products in any mar¬ 
keting area shall prohibit or in any manner limit, in the case 
of the products of milk, the marketing in that area of any 
milk or product thereof produced in any production area 
in the United States.” Section 8c(5)(G) of the Act, 7 
U.S.C. 60Sc(5)(G). Even if it should seem to be incident¬ 
ally necessary, in the light of the evidence in a hearing 
record, to prohibit the marketing of milk from a particular 
area or region, the statute expressly prohibits any such 
prohibition. Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Anderson (C.A. 8), 
157 F. 2d 87, cert, denied 329 U. S. 788; and Hood & Sons 
v. DuMond, 336 U. S. 525, 543-544. 

In addition, §8c(7) (D) provides that under the “inci¬ 
dental . . . and necessary” provision, no provision may 
be included which is “inconsistent with” the classification, 
pooling, and pricing provisions of § 8c(5) of the Act. An¬ 
other exception is in § 8c (13) (B) in which the statute states 
that no order shall be applicable to any producer “in his 
capacity as a producer.” 

The Act has, therefore, enumerated the provisos or limi¬ 
tations, and with those exceptions the “incidental . . . 









29 


and necessary” authorization is to have such coverage as 
the plain words may be said to include on the basis of the 
evidence in a hearing record. The exceptions in § 8c(5) (G) 
and § 8c(13)(B) from the operation of the classification, 
pooling, pricing, and “incidental . . . and necessary” 
authorizations in the statute preclude the enlargement of 
the exceptions by an addition, as contended for by the 
appellees. George Moore Ice Cream Co. v. Rose, 289 U. S. 
373. The textual meaning of the “incidental . . . and 
necessary” authorization is thus reinforced by the impli¬ 
cation that the exception in § 8c(5)(G), and the phrase in 
§ 8c(7)(D) prohibiting a provision “inconsistent with” 
the classification, pooling, and pricing provisions of § 8c(5), 
and the prohibition in § 8c(13)(B) are the only exceptions 
as to what may be included, in view of the evidence, as 
incidental and necessary to effectuate the other provisions 
of the order. Exceptions made in such detail preclude 
their enlargement by implication. The proscriptions in 
the Act give emphasis to the view that, aside from those 
limitations, the Congressional purpose was to permit the 
plain language of § 8c(7) (D) to be applied to any situation 
which, under the evidence, is incidental and necessary to 
the effectuation of the classification, pooling, and pricing 
provisions in the order. 21 

There are additional tokens of intention within the statute 
and outside of it. The Secretary is required by the Act to 
“accord such recognition and encouragement to producer- 
owned and producer-controlled co-operative associations as 


21 Section 8c (5) of the Act expressly recognizes that additional 
provisions, such as “incidental . . . and necessary,” may be in¬ 
cluded under § 8c (7). That §8c(5) does not enumerate all the 
terms and conditions that may be included in a milk order is also 
plainly evident by reference to § 10(b) (2) which requires that 
each order “relating to milk and its products . . . shall provide 
that each handler subject thereto shall pay to any authority or 
agency fi.e., the Market Administrator] established under such 
order such handler’s share (as approved by the Secretary) of 
such expenses as the Secretary may find will necessarily be incurred 
by such authority or agency, during any period specified by him, 
for the maintenance and functioning of such authority or agency.” 
7 U.S.C. 610(b) (2). 






30 


will be in harmony with the policy toward co-operative asso¬ 
ciations set forth in existing acts of Congress, and as will 
tend to promote efficient methods of marketing and distri¬ 
bution.” Section 10(b)(1) of the Act, 7 U.S.C. 610(b)(1). 
It was made clear in United States v. Rock Royal Co-oper¬ 
ative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 562-565, that different treatment 
and special considerations have been accorded to marketing 
cooperatives by state and congressional legislation alike, 
and that the “distinctions between such co-operatives and 
business organizations have repeatedly been held to justify 
different treatment.” Numerous acts of Congress deal 
with co-operatives differently from proprietary business 
enterprises, and enunciate the policy of aiding and encour¬ 
aging the establishment, operation, and growth of market- 
mg co-operatives.— 

The Agricultural Marketing Act of June 15, 1929, 46 
Stat. 18, 12 U.S.C. 1141, 1141 (j), expresses the policy of 
Congress to promote merchandising of agricultural com¬ 
modities in such a way as to put agriculture on a basis of 
economic equality with other industries, and this is to be 
accomplished by “encouraging the organization of produc¬ 
ers into effective associations of producers under their own 
control for greater unity of effort in marketing and by pro¬ 
moting the establishment and financing of a farm-market¬ 
ing system of producer-owned and producer-controlled co¬ 
operative associations and other agencies.” Some of the 
other instances of the Congressional policy of special con¬ 
sideration for, and treatment of, cooperatives are in the 
Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 730,15 U.S.C. 17; the Capper-Volstead 
Act, 42 Stat. 388, 7 U.S.C. 291; the Robin son-Patman Act 
of June 19, 1936, c. 592, s. 4, 49 Stat. 1528, 15 U.S.C. 13b; 

22 It was recognized at the time of the enactment of this legisla¬ 
tion for milk regulation that there is to be a continuing need, 
Tinder these programs, for co-operative action in searching for 
"additional outlets, the stimulation of demand, and the improve¬ 
ment of handling techniques at points where private trader enter¬ 
prise failed fully to serve the farmer’s interest.” Dr. E. G. Nourse 
(then Director of the Institute of Economics, Brookings Institution), 
American Cooperation, 1934, a collection of papers and discussions 
comprising the tenth summer session of The American Institute of 
Cooperation, p. 68. 



31 


and the Grain Futures Act, 42 Stat. 998, as amended and re¬ 
designated as the Commodity Exchange Act, 49 Stat. 1491, 

7 U.S.C. 10a. 

Although the special considerations extended by Con¬ 
gressional legislation to co-operatives may have resulted 
in some instances in competitive advantages to such asso¬ 
ciations, the difference between such associations and ordi¬ 
nary business organizations constitutes a reasonable and 
legal basis of classification. Flint v. Stone Tracy Co., 220 
U. S. 107, 173; Brushaber v. Union Pacific Railroad, Co. 
240 U. S. 1, 21; Chicago Board of Trade v. Olsen, 262 U. S. 
1; and In re Marketing Association of Fort Wayne, Inc., 

8 F. 2d 626. State legislation along the same pattern has 
been sustained. American Sugar Refining Co. v. Louisiana, 
179 TJ. S. 89; Liberty Warehouse Co. v. Burley Tobacco 
Growers Co-operative Marketing Association, 276 U. S. 71; 
and many other cases cited in United States v. Rock Royal 
Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 563, fn. 27. 

The fundamental basis 23 for special treatment of co¬ 
operatives by the legislature was explained by Judge (later 
Justice) Cardozo in People v. Teuscher, 248 N. Y. 454, 
463, as follows: 

“More and more, in its social engineering, the law is 
looking to co-operative effort by those within an indus¬ 
try as a force for social good. It is harnessing the 
power that is latent within groups as it is harnessing 
the power in wind and fall and stream. Conspicuously 
it is doing this in its dealings with agricultural pro¬ 
ducers, spread often over wide areas, and thus deficient 
in cohesion, but yielding up new energies when func¬ 
tioning together. We see this in the very statutes, 


23 An essential difference between a co-operative and a capital- 
stock corporation is that the latter is founded on the earning 
capacity of the capital invested—and that investment is the basis 
of administration, control, and distribution of earnings—but a 
co-operative, on the other hand, is founded for the mutual benefit 
of its members, and its earnings or profits are returned not on 
the basis of the capital which each member has contributed, but 
on the volume of his shipments and, therefore, on the basis of his 
use of the co-operative association. Nourse, The Legal Status of 
Agricultural Cooperation (The Institute of Economics, 1927), p. 89. 



32 


already quoted, with their attempt to check tuberculosis 
[in cattle] by co-operative effort [on the part of dairy 
farmers]. We see it in the co-operative marketing 
associations which have made such headway of recent 
years in this State and many others, associations with 
privileges and powers peculiar to themselves.” 

These declarations of Congressional policy with respect 
to co-operatives foreclose any argument that the “incidental 
. . . and necessary” authorization is to be given a cramp¬ 
ing construction so as to preclude, as a matter of law, its 
l>eing applicable to market-wide services performed by co¬ 
operatives. No basis appears for cutting down the scope 
of the natural meaning of the plain provision in the Act. 
In the absence of a basis to the contrary, it must be assumed 
that Congress evidently meant what these words ordinarily 
convey. Jones v. Liberty Glass Co., 332 U. S. 524, 531. The 
Congressional declarations are such that assuming, argu¬ 
endo, any question as to the scope of the legislative 
authorization, that question is to be resolved by an inter¬ 
pretation favorable to the view that Congress intended, 
whenever there is a warrant in the hearing record, for the 
“incidental . . . and necessary” provision to be appli¬ 
cable to co-operatives who perform market-wide services. 
These plain words of the Act are to be interpreted “in their 
ordinary, every-day sense” ( Crane v. Commissioner, 331 
C. S. 1, 6), and so as “to carry out in particular cases the 
generally expressed legislative policy.” Securities and 
Exchange Commission v. C. M. Joiner Leasing Corp., 320 
F. S. 344, 351. 

These Congressional declarations of policy as to co¬ 
operatives are consonant with Congressional action relative 
to this exact issue. The services for which deductions are 
allowed are described in the legislative history of a bill 
containing a clarifying amendment on this point. S. 3426, 
76th Cong., 3d Sess. This amendment was described in the 
Senate Committee Report (No. 1719, 76th Cong., 3d Sess., 
p. 8) as covering services “which are identifiable as bene¬ 
fiting all producers with a reasonable degree of equality 







33 


ns distinguished from services, the benefits of which are 
limited primarily to members of a particular cooperative 
association.” See to the same effect, Hearings, Subcom¬ 
mittee of Senate Committee on Agriculture and Forestry 
on S. 3426, 76th Cong., 3d Sess., pp. 52-53, 75. The services 
are described in 86 Cong. Rec. 12258-12259. The Senate 
report and the explanation to Congress {ibid.) shows that 
the object of the amendment proposed was to “establish 
more explicit standards,” thus avoiding the question of 
delegation of power, to guide the Secretary in making pay¬ 
ments which he was already authorized to make under his 
general power to prescribe minimum prices and the manner 
of paying produers. S. 3426, which contained a large num¬ 
ber of other amendments, passed the Senate (86 Cong. 
Rec. 12266) but died in the House committee; although 
other amendments had been vigorously opposed before the 
Senate Committee, this particular amendment had met with 
no objection (86 Cong. Rec. 12256). The action by the 
Senate indicates a legislative policy favorable to the inter¬ 
pretation by the Secretary as to the scope of the “incidental 
. . . and necessary” authorization in the Act. Sioux 

Tribe of Indians v. United States, 316 U. S. 317, 329; and 
Porter v. Murray (C.A. 1), 156 F. 2d 781, 785. The House, in 
failing to take any action on the bill, is not to be regarded as 
having disapproved co-operative payments in milk orders. 
Gemsco, Inc. v. Walling, 324 U. S. 244, 260-265. 

Additional reasons prevail in support of the view that the 
“incidental . . . and necessary” provisions in the Act 
should not be cut down by interpretation so as to be of 
negligible use, or no use, in dealing with the variant and 
complex situations in the fluid milk industry. 

The necessity of permitting the words of the Act to have 
their full meaning is revealed by the numerous instances in 
which, on the basis of the evidence at a public hearing, the 
Secretarv has had to include “incidental . . . and neces- 
sary” provisions in order to effectuate the classification, 
pooling, and pricing provisions in a milk order. The giving 
of a limited circumscription, as a matter of law, to the defini- 





34 


tive authority conferred on the Secretary would, in many 
instances, strangle the effectiveness of the programs."' 4 

The lower court’s opinion (Joint App. 142-150) gives an 
unwarranted rigidity to the application of the word “neces¬ 
sary.” It is clear that, in a remedial statute, the word 
“necessary” does not mean “indispensable” or “essen- 
tial” or “vital.” Armour & Co. v. Wamtock, 323 U. S. 126, 
129-132; and Borden Co. v. Borella, 325 U. S. 679, 682-684. 
The authorization in the Act to include incidental and neces¬ 
sary provisions in order to effectuate the measures enu¬ 
merated in the Act must include such provisions as are 
reasonably suitable for carrying into execution the powers 
expressly granted. Gemsco, Inc. v. Walling , 324 IT. S. 244. 

- 4 E. g., the St. Louis milk order provides (7 CFR, 903.3(a)! 
that, in establishing the classification of milk received by a handler 
from producers, “the burden rests upon such handler to account 
for such milk and to prove to the Market Administrator that such 
milk should not be classified as Class I milk.” This type of pro¬ 
vision was held valid in United States v. Ridgeland Creamery Co. 
(D.C. W.D. Wise.), 47 F. Supp. 145, 149; and Bailey Farm Dairy 
Co. v. Jones (D.C. E.D. Mo.), 61 F. Supp. 209, 225, affirmed 
Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Anderson (C.A. 8), 157 F. 2d 87. A 
similar provision is included in 27 other milk orders. Another 
provision based on the “incidental . . . and necessary” authoriza¬ 
tion in the statute is in the Louisville milk order (7 CFR, 946.7 
(b)(3) and 946.8(d)(2)) whereby certain sums arc deducted in 
April. May, and June of each year and then paid to producers in 
September, October, and November in order to offer an incentive 
to minimize seasonality of production. See, The Louisville Fall- 
Premium Plan for Seasonal Milk Pricing (Kentucky Agricultural 
Experiment Station, University of Kentucky) Bulletin 510. A 
similar provision is in four orders. A provision for the “termina¬ 
tion of obligations” has been included in twenty-seven orders (14 
F.R. 791-794). Provisions relative to monthly reports by handlers, 
records to be kept, and authorization for audit review are set forth 
in all orders whereby the various obligations of handlers may be 
computed and verified. The New York order contains (7 CFR, 
927.9 (h)) provisions for compensatory payments with respect to 
non-pooled milk. A similar provision is included in eleven other 
orders. Provisions for the accounting of inter-handler sales arc 
included in thirty orders; requirements with respect to interest 
are set forth in five orders; provisions for the designation of pool 
plants and the cancellation of pool plants are in a number of orders, 
as well as a percental requirement for Class I milk; and thirteen 
orders contain requirements with respect to the accounting for milk 
received from undisclosed sources. 





35 


The “incidental . . . and necessary” provision is to 
be viewed as a part of the whole texture of the Act and of 
the economy to which the Act applies. 2 ' Broad standards 
for administrative action “is a reflection of the necessities 
of modern legislation dealing with complex economic and 
social problems.” Sunshine Anthracite Coal Co. v. Adkins, 
310 U. S. 381, 398. It is apparent ( American Power & 
Light Co. v. Securities and Exchange Commission, 329 U. S. 
90, 105) that 

“The legislative process would frequently bog down 
if Congress were . . . required to appraise before¬ 
hand the myriad situations to which it wishes a par¬ 
ticular policy to be applied and to formulate specific 
rules for each situation. Necessity therefore fixes a 
point beyond which it is unreasonable and impracti¬ 
cable to compel Congress to prescribe detailed rules. 


In deciding whether certain administrative action was 
“necessary to ensure” the effectuation of § 11(b)(2) of the 
Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935 (49 Stat. 803, 
821; 15 U. S. C. 79k(b)(2)), it was held that Congress had 
entrusted to the administrative agency “the responsibility 
of selecting the means of achieving the statutory policy” 
and the relation of ‘ ‘ remedy to policy is peculiarly a matter 
for administrative competence,” and its “judgment is en¬ 
titled to the greatest weight.” American Power & Light 
Co. v. Securities and Exchange Commission, 329 U. S. 90, 
112. Assuming, arguendo, that the plain language of the 

25 The mutable circumstances to be dealt with in the classifica¬ 
tion, pooling, and pricing of milk are such that the statutory 
authorization in England for milk regulation sets forth an “incidental 
. . . and necessary” provision. Certain provisions may be included 
in the regulations in England and, in addition, “such matters as 
are incidental to or consequential on the provisions of this Act” 
relating to the regulations “or are necessary for giving effect to 
those provisions.” Agricultural Marketing Act, 1931, 21 and 22 
Geo. 5 c. 42, § 6 (Vol. 1, Halsbury’s Statutes of England, 2d ed., 
p. 243). The regulation of milk marketing in England is discussed 
in the Milk Report of Reorganization Commission for Great Britain 
(Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries, Economic Series No. 44), 
pp. 6-117. 



36 


Act is susceptible of either of two opposed interpretations, 
it is to be read in the manner which effectuates rather than 
frustrates the major purpose. Shapiro v. United States, 
333 U. S. 1, 31. 

The statute’s terms, background, purposes, and history 
give convincing evidence of the Congressional intention for 
the “incidental . . . and necessary” provision in the 

Act to have the plain, unqualified meaning that those words 
ordinarily convey. 26 

D. The Scope of Judicial Review Is Limited to the 
Inquiry as to Whether Substantial Evidence in the 
Hearing Record, on Which the Secretary's Order Is 
Based, Supports the Secretary's Action. There Being 
No Question That Substantial Evidence Supports the 
Secretary's Findings That the Order Provisions for 
Payments to Co-operatives Are Incidental and Neces¬ 
sary Under Section 8c(7)(D) of the Act, and Not In¬ 
consistent with Section 8c(5), and Inasmuch as the 
Appellees Failed to Place the Entire Hearing Record 
Before the Court, the Appellees' Attack Upon the Pro¬ 
visions of the Order Must Fail. 

The scope of judicial review under §8c(15) of the Act, 
providing the procedure wdiereby a handler may question 
the legality of an order or a provision in it, is limited to 
the inquiry as to whether substantial evidence supports the 
order of the Secretary. Wetmiller Dairy & Farm Products, 
Inc. v. Wickard (C. A. 2), 149 F. 2d 330; Wawa Dairy Farms 
v. Wickard (C. A. 3), 149 F. 2d 860; New York State Guern¬ 
sey Breeders' Co-operative Association v. Wickard (C. A. 
2), 141 F. 2d 805, cert, denied, 323 U. S. 725; Waddington 
Milk Co. v. Wickard (C. A. 2), 140 F. 2d 97; Queensboro 
Farm Products Inc. v. Wickard, 47 F. Supp. 206, affirmed 
(C. A. 2), 137 F. 2d 969; Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Jones, 
61 F. Supp. 209, affirmed (C. A. 8), 157 F. 2d 87; Crull v. 
Wickard (C. A. 6), 137 F. 2d 406; and Titusville Dairy Prod¬ 
ucts Co. v. Brannon (C. A. 3), 176 F. 2d 332, 336. 

The Act is silent as to the scope of judicial review when— 


26 This is subject only to the exceptions enumerated in the Act, 
supra, pp. 28-29. 






37 


as in this action—dairy farmers, who are not handlers, 
attack as illegal an order or a provision of an order. It 
is settled, however, that the substantial evidence test is 
applied by the courts in reviewing administrative action, 
based on a hearing record, so long as no other standard is 
specifically prescribed by statute. Shields v. Utah Idaho 
Central R. Co., 305 U. S. 177. The validity, therefore, of 
the provisions in the order is to be tested by whether sub¬ 
stantial evidence in the hearing record before the Secretary 
supports the findings. 

The substantial evidence test, with respect to administra¬ 
tive findings based on a hearing record, has been approved 
by this Court as meaning that “the findings of fact must 
be sustained if supported by substantial evidence and those 
findings cannot be set aside simply because different infer¬ 
ences may be drawn from the evidence,” and the require¬ 
ment that there must be substantial evidence “does not 
require that there be proof beyond a reasonable doubt, . . . 
but only such ‘relevant evidence as a reasonable mind might 
accept as adequate to support a conclusion.’ ” Hughes v. 
Securities and Exchange Commission, (C. A. D. C.), App. 
D. C. ,174 F. 2d 969, 974. Congress gave to the Secretary, 
not to the courts, the power to draw inferences from the 
facts in the hearing record and to appraise conflicting and 
circumstantial evidence. It is not, therefore, for the courts 
to weigh conflicting testimony or pass upon the credibility 
of witnesses or reject inferences drawn by the Secretary, 
from the facts in the hearing record, merely because dif¬ 
ferent inferences might seem to be more reasonable. Inter¬ 
state Commerce Commission v. Jersey City, 322 U. S. 503; 
National Labor Relations Board v. Southern Bell T. <& T. 
Co., 319 U. S. 50; Gray v. Powell, 314 U. S. 402; Interstate 
Commerce Commission v. Union Pacific R. Co., 222 U. S. 
541; and Victor Mfg. & Gasket Co. v. National Labor Rela¬ 
tions Board (C. A. 7), 174 F. 2d 867, 868. 

This scope of judicial review is consonant with the char¬ 
acterization of the review procedure provided in the Act 
in United Stales v. Ruzicka, 329 U. S. 287, in which it was 
stated that the questions presented even when formulated 






38 


in constitutional terms, arise out of, or are entwined with, 
“factors that call for understanding of the milk industry,” 
and any review of the Secretary’s action is limited to the 
basis of his ruling and of the elucidation w r hich he gave to 
his ruling. This is in accord wdth the prevailing principle, 
under other statutes providing for administrative action 
subject to review by the courts, that in reviewing even the 
“ultimate conclusions” of the administrative agency, it 
is not the Court’s function to substitute its own infer¬ 
ences of fact for the agency’s where the latter have support 
in the record, and as to questions of law involving the specific 
application of a broad statutory term, in a proceeding in 
which the agency administering the statute must determine 
it initially, the reviewing Court’s function is limited, and 
the agency’s determination, if not prohibited by the 
statute, is to be accepted if it is supported by substantial 
evidence. Cardillo v. Liberty Mutual Insurance Co., 
330 U. S. 469; National Labor Relations Board v. 
Hearst Publications, 322 U. S. Ill; Dobson v. Com¬ 
missioner, 320 U. S. 489; National Labor Relations 
Board v. Nevada Copper Corp., 316 U. S. 105; Gray v. 
Powell, 314 U. S. 402, 412-13; South Chicago Coal & Dock 
Co. v. Bassett, 309 U. S. 251; Parker v. Motor Boat Sales, 
Inc.. 314 U. S. 244; Rochester Telephone Corp. v. United 
States, 307 U. S. 125; and Swayne & Hoyt v. United States, 
300 U. S. 297. 

The complaint presents no issue as to whether substantial 
evidence supports the Secretary’s findings. The sole issue 
is whether, under the terms of the statute, any such pro¬ 
vision for payments to cooperatives for services to the 
market as a whole could, under any circumstances, be in¬ 
cluded in a milk order. The appellees’ argument assumes 
that there is some simple clear test which the courts use in 
dealing with what is “incidental . . . and necessary” 
wherebv it can be determined, without reference to the 
facts, whether particular provisions are or are not inci¬ 
dental and necessary to the classification, pooling, and 
pricing provisions in the milk order. That argument, of 
course, would seem to be equally applicable to the statu¬ 
tory provisions for classification, pooling, and pricing, and 






39 


those provisions in the Act would likewise be interpreted 
without regard to the facts presented. Nothing in the 
statute’s background, terms, or purposes indicates its scope 
to be limited in any such unusual manner; nothing indicates 
that the term “incidental . . . and necessary” is to be 
regarded as a term of art having, as a matter of law, a 
definite and restricted meaning so that its application is 
to be ascertained in vacuo. Any such scope of judicial 
review would ignore the canonical rule that a regulatory 
statute, dealing with complex or variant situations, must 
be read in the light of the mischief to be corrected and the 
end to be attained, and action taken on the basis of a hear¬ 
ing record is to be tested by whether the action has war¬ 
rant in the evidence. National Labor Relations Board v. 
Hearst Publications , 322 U. S. 111. 

Substantial evidence supports, supra pp. 12-25, the Sec¬ 
retary’s finding in the application of the “incidental . . . 
and necessary” authorization in the Act in the issuance* 7 
of the amended order, effective August 1, 1941. The plain 
■words of the statutory provision, in their ordinary accep¬ 
tation and in that sense in which the Congress has obviously 
used the terms, permits the inclusion in a milk order of 
any provision 28 which, on the basis of the hearing record, 
is incidental to the classification and pricing provisions 
and necessary to effectuate those provisions. Any such 
application of the statute must, therefore, be decided on 
the basis of the evidence in the hearing record, and if sub¬ 
stantial evidence supports the Secretary’s action, the pro¬ 
visions of the order are to be sustained on judicial review. 

Assuming, arguendo , that the complaint presents an issue 
as to whether substantial evidence in the hearing record 
supports the provisions in the order, the record shows, 


27 The co-operative payment provisions in the order were sub¬ 
sequently amended. The hearing record on which the subsequent 
amendments are based is not before the Court. 

28 This is subject to the statutory exceptions discussed, infra, 
pp. 28-29. The findings by the Secretary are that these provisions 
in the order are not inconsistent with §8c(5) of the Act, and 
these findings, supported by substantial evidence, cannot be success¬ 
fully challenged. 




40 


supra, pp. 12-25, the basis in reason for the findings of the 
Secretary in issuing the amendments of August 1, 1941, 
providing for the payments to co-operatives. But the judg¬ 
ment of the lower court applies to the program as subse¬ 
quently amended, and the hearing record on which the Sec- 
retan.’ based the subsequent amendments of August 1,1947, 
dealing with payments to co-operatives, is not in the record 
of this case. The amendments now in effect are different in 
various respects from the original provisions for payments 
to be made to the co-operatives. If the appellees seek to 
attack the present provisions in the order as not being 
based on substantial evidence, the attack fails because the 
record on which the present provisions are based is not 
before the Court. The findings of the Secretary, on the 
basis of the evidence at a public hearing, carry a presump¬ 
tion of the existence of a state of facts justifying the action. 
United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 
533, 567-568; Thompson v. Consolidated Gas Utilities Corp., 
300 TJ. S. 55, 69; Wallace v. Hudson-Duncan & Co. (C. A. 9), 
98 F. 2d 985; and Queensboro Farms Products v. Wickard 
(C. A. 2), 137 F. 2d 969, 977-981. 


II. The Challenged Provisions Are Plainly Author¬ 
ized by the Act, and the Government’s Motion for Sum¬ 
mary Judgment Should Have Been Sustained. 

The Government filed a motion for summary judgment 
(Joint App. 58), and a copy of the hearing record on which 
the 1941 amendments were based 20 was before the Court 
with respect to the motion for summary judgment. The 
scope of judicial review was limited to a review of that 
record, supra, pp. 36-39; no new evidence was admissible. 
Consequently the action should have been disposed of by 
that motion for summary judgment. This principle was 
established in Wawa Dairy Farms v. Wickard (C. A. 3), 
149 F. 2d 860, 864: 

29 At the time of the motion for summary judgment, the sub¬ 
sequent 1947 amendments had not been issued, and the hearing 
record before the Court was the complete record at that time. 
Even if it had not been complete, the appellees could have supplied 
any omission; and summary judgment would have been proper. 


41 


“Summary judgment procedure was properly uti¬ 
lized herein. Appellant insists that the instant matter 
involves genuine issues as to material facts and there¬ 
fore that under Rule 56 of the Federal Rules of Civil 
Procedure, 28 U. S. C. A. following section 723c, its 
disposition on a motion for summary judgment was 
error. According to the district court’s reasoning, 
since its decision had to be based on the record before 
the Secretary of Agriculture and not upon a trial de 
novo, it could consider that record alone whether the 
case went to trial or was terminated upon motion for 
summary judgment. Obviously, the summary judg¬ 
ment was proper.” 

The bill of complaint, as amended, fails to present an 
issue as to whether the provisions, in the amended order, 
alleged to be illegal are not based on substantial evidence in 
the hearing record on which the amended order was issued. 
The sole issue presented by the plaintiffs is whether the 
challenged provisions in the order are, as a matter of statu¬ 
tory interpretation, within the framework of the Act. 

The Act authorizes “incidental . . . and necessary” 
provisions, and the Secretary made findings of fact, on the 
basis of the evidence before him, that the provisions for 
payments to co-operatives, for market-wide services, are 
incidental and necessary to the effectuation of the classifica¬ 
tion, pooling, and pricing provisions under § 8c(5) of the 
Act, and that such payments to co-operatives, for market¬ 
wide services, are not inconsistent with § 8c(5). There is 
no basis for concluding that, as a matter of statutory in¬ 
terpretation, these provisions cannot be included in a milk 
order, supra, pp. 9-36. 

There is no issue of fact in the case. The provisions in 
the order are authorized by the Act. The Government’s 
motion for summary judgment should have been granted 
by the lower court and the complaint dismissed. 




42 


CONCLUSION 

For the foregoing reasons the judgment of the lower 
court, sustaining the amended bill of complaint, should be 
reversed and the amended complaint should be dismissed. 

J. Stephen Doyle, Jr., 

Neil Brooks, 

Special Assistants to the 

Attorney General; 
Lewis A. Sigler, 

Assistant Associate Solicitor; 
Mary Connor Myers, 

Attorney, 

United States Department of Agriculture. 









43 


APPENDIX 

The following are relevant sections of the Agricultural 
Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (7 U. S. C. 601 et seq.): 

$ 60Se. Orders Regulating Handling of Commodity. 

(1) Issuance by Secretary. 

Sec. 8c. (1) The Secretary of Agriculture shall, subject 
to the provisions of this section, issue, and from time to time 
amend, orders applicable to processors, associations of 
producers, and others engaged in the handling of any agri¬ 
cultural commodity or product thereof specified in subsec¬ 
tion (2) of this section. Such orders shall regulate, in the 
manner hereinafter in this section provided, only such 
handling of such agricultural commodity, or product 
thereof, as is in the current of interstate or foreign com¬ 
merce, or which directly burdens, obstructs, or affects, inter¬ 
state or foreign commerce in such commodity or product 
thereof. 

• * « • • 

(3) Notice and Hearing. 

(3) Whenever the Secretary of Agriculture has reason to 
believe that the issuance of an order will tend to effectuate 
the declared policy of this title with respect to any com¬ 
modity or product thereof specified in subsection (2) of this 
section, he shall give due notice of and an opportunity for 
a hearing upon a proposed order. 

(4) Finding and Issuance of Order. 

(4) After such notice and opportunity for hearing, the 
Secretary of Agriculture shall issue an order if he finds, 
and sets forth in such order, upon the evidence introduced 
at such hearing (in addition to such other findings as may 
be specifically required by this section) that the issuance 
of such order and all of the terms and conditions thereof 
will tend to effectuate the declared policy of this title with 
respect to such commodity. 

(5) Milk and Its Products; Terms and Conditions of 

Orders. 

(5) In the case of milk and its products, orders issued 
pursuant to this section shall contain one or more of the 
following terms and conditions, and (except as provided in 
subsection (7) no others: 




44 


(A) Classifying milk in accordance with the form in 
which or the purpose for which it is used, and fixing, or pro¬ 
viding a method for fixing, minimum prices for each such 
use classification winch all handlers shall pay, and the time 
when payments shall be made, for milk purchased from 
producers or associations of producers. Such prices shall 
be uniform as to all handlers, subject only to adjustments 
for (1) volume, market, and production differentials custo¬ 
marily applied by the handlers subject to such order, (2) the 
grade or quality of the milk purchased, and (3) the loca¬ 
tions at which delivery of such milk, or any use classifica¬ 
tion thereof, is made to such handlers. 

(B) Providing: 

(i) for the payment to all producers and associa¬ 
tions of producers delivering milk to the same handler 
of uniform prices for all milk delivered by them: Pro¬ 
vided, That, except in the case of orders covering milk 
products only, such provision is approved or favored 
by at least three-fourths of the producers who, during 
a representative period determined by the Secretary 
of Agriculture, have been engaged in the production for 
market of milk covered in such order or by producers 
who, during such representative period, have produced 
at least three-fourths of the volume of such milk pro¬ 
duced for market during such period; the approval 
required hereunder shall be separate and apart from 
any other approval or disapproval provided for by this 
section; or 

(ii) for the payment to all producers and associa¬ 
tions of producers delivering milk to all handlers of 
uniform prices for all milk so delivered, irrespective of 
the uses made of such milk by the individual handler 
to whom it is delivered; 

subject, in either case, only to adjustments for (a) volume, 
market, and production differentials customarily applied 
by the handlers subject to such order, (b) the grade or 
quality of the milk delivered, (c) the locations at which de¬ 
livery of such milk is made, and (d) a further adjustment, 
equitably to apportion the total value of the milk pur¬ 
chased by any handler, or by all handlers, among producers 
and associations of producers, on the basis of their market¬ 
ings of milk during a representative period of time. 

(C) In order to accomplish the purposes set forth in 
paragraphs (A) and (B) of this subsection (5), providing 






45 


a method for making adjustments in payments, as among 
handlers (including producers who are also handlers), to the 
end that the total sums paid by each handler shall equal the 
value of the milk purchased by him at the prices fixed in 
accordance with paragraph (A) hereof. 

(D) Providing that, in the case of all milk purchased by 
handlers from any producer who did not regularly sell milk 
during a period of 30 days next preceding the effective date 
of such order for consumption in the area covered thereby, 
payments to such producer, for the period beginning with 
the first regular delivery by such producer and continuing 
until the end of two full calendar months following the first 
day of the next succeeding calendar month, shall be made 
at the price for the lowest use classification specified in such 
order, subject to the adjustments specified in paragraph 
(B) of this subsection (5). 

(E) Providing (i) except as to producers for whom such 
services are being rendered by a cooperative marketing 
association, qualified as provided in paragraph (F) of this 
subsection (5), for market information to producers and for 
the verification of weights, sampling, and testing of milk 
purchased from producers, and for making appropriate 
deductions therefor from payments to producers, and (ii) 
for assurance of, and security for, the payment by handlers 
for milk purchased. 

(F) Nothing contained in this subsection (5) is intended 
or shall be construed to prevent a cooperative marketing 
association qualified under the provisions of the Act of 
Congress of February 18, 1922, as amended, known as the 
“Capper-Volstead Act,” engaged in making collective sales 
or marketing of milk or its products for the producers 
thereof, from blending the net proceeds of all its sales in 
all markets in all use classifications, and making distribu¬ 
tion thereof to its producers in accordance with the contract 
between the association and its producers: Provided, That 
it shall not sell milk or its products to any handler for use or 
consumption in any market at prices less than the prices 
fixed pursuant to paragraph (A) of this subsection (5) for 
such milk. 

(G) No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk 
and its products in any marketing area shall prohibit or in 
any manner limit, in the case of the products of milk, the 
marketing in that area of any milk or product thereof pro¬ 
duced in any production area in the United States. 

• • • • • 



46 


(7) Terms Common to All Orders. 

(7) In the case of the agricultural commodities and the 
products thereof specified in subsection (2) orders shall 
contain one or more of the following terms and conditions: 

(A) Prohibiting unfair methods of competition and un¬ 
fair trade practices in the handling thereof. 

(B) Providing that (except for milk and cream to be sold 
for consumption in fluid form) such commodity or product 
thereof, or any grade, size, or quality thereof shall be sold 
by the handlers thereof only at prices filed by such handlers 
in the manner provided in such order. 

(C) Providing for the selection by the Secretary of Agri¬ 
culture, or a method for the selection, of an agency or 
agencies and defining their power and duties, vrhich shall 
include only the powers: 

(i) To administer such order in accordance with its 
terms and provisions; 

(ii) To make rules and regulations to effectuate the 
terms and provisions of such order; 

(iii) To receive, investigate, and report to the Secre¬ 
tary of Agriculture complaints of violations of such 
order; and 

(iv) To recommend to the Secretary of Agriculture 
amendments to such order. 

Xo person acting as a member of an agency established pur¬ 
suant to this paragraph (C) shall be deemed to be acting 
in an official capacity, within the meaning of section 10 (g) 
of this title, unless such person receives compensation for 
his personal services from funds of the United States. 

(D) Incidental to, and not inconsistent with, the terms 
and conditions specified in subsections (5), (6), and (7) 
and necessary to effectuate the other provisions of such 
order. 

The following are relevant sections of the Boston milk 
marketing order, as amended (12 F.R. 4921, 7 CFR, 1947 
Supp., 904.0 et $eq.): 

§ 904.10 Payment to cooperative associations —(a) Appli¬ 
cation and qualification for cooperative payments. Any 
cooperative association of producers duly organized under 
the laws of any state may apply to the Secretary for a deter¬ 
mination that it is qualified to receive cooperative payments 



47 


in accordance with the provisions of this section. Upon 
notice of the filing of such an application, the market admin¬ 
istrator shall set aside for each month, from the funds 
provided by handlers ’ payments to the market administra¬ 
tor pursuant to § 904.9, such amount as he estimates is 
ample to make payment to the applicant, and hold it in 
reserve until the Secretary has ruled upon the application. 
The applicant association shall be considered to be a 
qualified association entitled to receive such payments 
from the date fixed by the Secretary, if he determines 
that it meets all of the following requirements. 

(1) It conforms to the requirements relating to character 
of organization, voting, dividend payments, and dealing 
in products of nonmembers, which are set forth in the 
Capper-Volstead Act and in the state laws under which 
the association is organized. 

(2) It operates as a responsible producer-controlled 
marketing association exercising full authority in the sale 
of the milk of its members. 

(3) It systematically checks the weights and tests of milk 
which its members deliver to plants not operated by the 
association. 

(4) It guarantees payment to its members for milk deliv¬ 
ered to plants not operated by the association. 

(5) It maintains, either individually or together with 
other qualified associations, a competent staff for dealing 
with marketing problems and for providing information to 
its members. 

(6) It constantly maintains close working relationships 
with its members. 

(7) It collaborates with similar associations in activities 
incident to the maintenance and strengthening of collective 
bargaining by producers and the operation of a plan of uni¬ 
form pricing of milk to handlers. 

(8) It is in compliance with all applicable provisions of 
this order. 

(b) Cooperative payments . On or before the 25th day 
after the end of each month, each qualified association shall 
be entitled to receive a cooperative payment from the funds 
provided by handlers’ payments to the market administra¬ 
tor pursuant to § 904.9. The payment shall be made under 




48 


the conditions and at the rates specified in this paragraph, 
and shall be subject to verification of the receipts and other 
items upon which such payment is based. 

(1) Each qualified association shall be entitled to pay¬ 
ment at the rate of 1 cent per hundredweight on the milk 
w’hich its producer members deliver to the plant of a handler 
other than a qualified association; except on milk delivered 
by a producer who is also a member of another qualified 
association, and on milk delivered to a handler who fails 
to make applicable payments pursuant to § 904.9 (b) (2) 
and § 904.11 within 10 days after the end of the month in 
which he is required to do so. If the handler is required 
by paragraph (e) of this section to make deductions from 
members of the association at a rate lower than 1 cent per 
hundredweight, the payment pursuant to this subparagraph 
shall be at such lower rate. 

(2) Each qualified association shall be entitled to pay¬ 
ment at the rate of 2 cents per hundredweight on milk re¬ 
ceived from producers at a plant operated by that associa¬ 
tion. 

(c) Reports relating to cooperative payments. Each 
qualified association shall, upon request by the market 
administrator, make reports to him with respect to its use 
of cooperative payments and its performance in meeting 
the requirements set forth as the basis for such payments, 
and shall file with him a copy of its balance sheet and oper¬ 
ating statement at the close of each fiscal year. 

(d) Suspension of Cooperative payments. Whenever 
there is reason to believe that an association is no longer 
meeting the qualification requirements, the market admin¬ 
istrator shall, upon request by the Secretary, suspend 
cooperative payments to it, and shall give the association 
written notice of the suspension. Such suspended pay¬ 
ments shall be held in reserve until the Secretary has, 
after notice and opportunity for a hearing, ruled upon the 
performance of the association. 

(e) Deductions from payments to members. (1) Each 
association which is entitled to receive cooperative pay¬ 
ments on milk which its producer members deliver to a 
handler other than a qualified association may file a claim 
with the handler for amounts to be deducted from the 
handler’s payments to such members. The claim shall con¬ 
tain a list of the producers, an agreement to indemnify the 








49 


handler in the making of the deductions, and a certification 
that the association has an unterminated membership con¬ 
tract with each producer, authorizing the claimed deduction. 

(2) In making payments to his producers for milk re¬ 
ceived during the month, each handler shall make deductions 
in accordance with the association’s claim, and shall pay 
the amount deducted to the association within 25 days after 
the end of the month. 


tto 


ft U. «. SOVtNNNINT PRINTING OPPICCi l«4» 


(•ltd 





United 


(Court of Appeals 


Nos. 10,365 and 10,366 


ON APPEAL FEOM A JUDGMENT OF TEE UNITED 8TATES 
DISTRICT COURT FOB THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA 


Edward B. Hanify, 

Boston, Mass. 

Harry Poukoff, 

New York City 
Attorneys for Appellees. 

United States Court of Appeals 
for the 

District of Columbia Circuit 


Edgar J. Goodrich 

Lxpmah Bedmah 
Bing Building 
Washington, D. C 
Of Counsel 

















1 


INDEX 

Page 


COUNTERSTATEMENT OF THE CASE. 1 

SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT . 5 

ARGUMENT: 

I. The Contested Provisions are not Authorized by, 

AND ARE NOT “INCIDENTAL TO 7 ’, ANY OF THE TERMS OF 

a Milk Order Prescribed in Section 8c(5). 9 

II. The Cooperative Payment Provisions are Inconsis¬ 
tent with the Terms of a Milk Order Prescribed in 
Section 8c(5) (B) and (E). 23 


III. There is Nothing in Alleged Contemporaneous Leg¬ 
islation, Subsequent Legislative History, or other 


Provisions of the Act to Support the Conclusion 
that the Cooperative Payment Deduction is Au¬ 
thorized . 29 

IV. The District Court Properly Applied Correct Prin¬ 
ciples Governing the Scope of Judicial Review in 
this Case. 33 

V. The Appellees have Standing to Sue, and the Inter- 
venor-Appellant’s Charge of Champerty and Main¬ 
tenance is Groundless. 37 

















ii 

CITATIONS 

Page 

Cases: 

Adler v. Seaman, 266 Fed. 828, 842-3. 37 

Carey v. Donohue, 240 U. S. 430, 437. 31 

Chandler <£- Price Co. v. Brandtjen cfc Klug, Inc., 296 

U. S. 53. 58 . 36 

Farmer Union Coop. Supply Co. v. United States, 25 F. 

Supp. 93 . 32 

Federal Trade Commission v. Bunte Bros., 312 U. S. 349, 

352 . 30 

Interstate Commerce Commission v. Cincinnati St. Ry. 

Co., 167 U. S. 479, 510. 34 

John v. ('hampagne Lumber Co., 157 Fed. 407, 418.... 39 

Mueller v. Adler, 292 Fed. 138. 37 

Reynolds Pen Co. v. Marshall Field <£■ Co., 8 F.R.D. 314 37 

Saginaic Broadcasting Co. v. F.C.C., 68 App. D. C. 282, 

96 F. (2d) 554. 560 . 35 

Salem Engineering Co. v. National Supply Co., 75 F. 

Supp. 993 . 37 

Schechtcr v. United States, 295 U. S. 495 . 15 

Schuster v. Ohio Farmers’ Cooperative Milk Ass’n, 61 F. 

(2d) 339 . 32 

Social Security Board v. Nierotko, 327 U. S. 358, 368-369 34 

Stark v. Bran nan, 82 F. Supp. 614 

8, 12, 16, 17, 20, 23, 34, 36, 39, 40 

Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288.8, 17, 21, 27, 34, 36, 40 

Stale v. Diary Distributors Inc., 217 Wis. 167, 258 N.W. 

383 . 21 

Texas Pacific Ry. Co. v. United States, 289 U. S. 627, 

640 . 34 

United States v. Butler, 297 U. S. 1. 11 

United States v. Rock Royal Cooperative, Inc., 307 U. S. 

533 . 16,30 


















Ill 


Statutes: 


Page 


Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1935 (Act of Aug. 24, 

1935, c. 641, §5, 49 Stat., 750, U.S.C., Title 7, §601 
et seq.) .30,31 

Section 10(b), (U.S.C., Title 7, §610(b))... .13, 15, 31, 32 

Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (Act of 
June 3, 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 246, U.S.C., Title 7, 

§601 et seq.) .5, 30, 31 

Section 8c (4), (U.S.C., Title 7, §608c(4)). 36 

Section 8c(5).5, 6, 9, 12, 16, 24, 29, 30 


Section 8c(5) (A) .6, 9, 12, 26 

Section 8c(5) (B).6, 7, 9,11, 12, 14, 18, 22, 23, 24, 26 

Section 8c(5)(C) .26,27,31 

Section 8c(5) (D) . 14,22 

Section 8c(5) (E) .12, 13, 27, 28, 29 

Section 8c(5) (F).13, 28, 32 

Section 8c(6) (D).14,22,23 

Section 8c(6) (E).7, 14, 22 

Section 8c(7) . 16,30 

Section 8c(7)(D) .5, 16, 18, 23, 24, 34 

Section 8c(12). 13,32 

Section 8c (17) . 36 

Section 671, (U.S.C., Title 7, §671). 32 

Capper-V olstead Act, Act of Feb. 18,1922, c. 57, 42 Stat. 

388, U.S.C., Title 7, §291. 31 

Clayton Act, Act of Oct. 15, 1914, c. 323, 38 Stat. 730, 

U.S.C., Title 15, §17. 31 

Internal Revenue Code, Act of May 10, 1934, c. 277, 

§101, 48 Stat. 700, U.S.C., Title 26, §103 (12) (1934 
ed.) . 31 























IV 


Page 

New York Statutes: 

Chap. 383, Laws of 1937. 30 

Chap. 760, Laws of 1939. 30 

Milk Orders: 

Boston Order.1, 2, 3, 4, 7, 8, 18, 19, 24, 28, 29, 34, 35, 36 

Dayton-Springfield Order. 25 

Fall River, Mass. Order. 25 

Kansas City Order. 25 

La Porte County, Indiana Order. 25 

Minneapolis-St. Paul Order. 25 

New Orleans Order . 25 

Quad Cities Order. 25 

Wichita Order. 25 

Committee Reports , Statements , and Proposed Bills: 

79 Cong. Rec. 9461-9462, 9480 . 15 

House Report No. 1241, 74th Congr., 1st Sess.. .9, 14, 15, 26, 33 

House Report No. 468, 75th Congr., 1st Sess. 11 

Senate Report No. 1011, 74th Congr., 1st Sess.10, 11, 16 

Statement by Chairman of the House Committee on 
Agriculture. 79 Cong. Rec. 9461. 15 

Statements by Davis, Administrator of the Agricutural 
Adjustment Act . 32,33 

Senate Bill No. 3426, 75th Congr., 3rd Sess. 30 

Miscellaneous: 

Department of Agriculture publications. 11 

3 Moore’s Federal Practice (1938) §56.09. 8 

Notice of report filed by Acting Director of Food Dis¬ 
tribution on March 18, 1944 (9 F.R. 3057-3060). 36 

6 Williston, Contracts (Rev. Ed. 1937) §1714. 39 
























Untteii States Gkmrt of Appeals 

For the District of Columbia Circuit 
October Term, 1949 


Nos. 10,365 and 10,366 

Charles F. Bran nan, Secretary of Agriculture, 

Appellant 

Dairymen’s League Co-operative Association, Inc., 
Intervenor-Appellant 


v. 

Delbert 0. Stark, et al., Appellees 


ON APPEAL FROM A JUDGMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 
DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA 


BRIEF FOR DELBERT O. STARK, ET AL., 

APPELLEES 


COUNTERSTATEMENT OF THE CASE 

The following facts found by the District Court are 
material to the consideration of the question presented on 
this Appeal. 

Order No. 4, Regulating the Handling of Milk in the 
Greater Boston, Massachusetts Marketing Area was origi¬ 
nally issued by the Secretary of Agriculture, effective Feb¬ 
ruary 9, 1936. Among other times, it was amended after 
public hearings on July 28, 1941, effective August 1, 1941 
(Joint App. 150). 

Under Order No. 4 as originally issued and amended, all 
milk sold bv dairv farmers is divided into two classes: 

m 

Class I, milk sold for use as fluid milk; and Class II, milk 
sold for use for other purposes, such as manufacture of 



2 


butter and cheese (Joint App. 151). The Order creates an 
equalization plan whereby every dairy farmer (generally 
known as “producer”) receives a proportionate share of 
the total proceeds of all milk sold in the marketing area, 
irrespective of whether his milk is used by the purchaser 
as Class I or Class II milk (Joint App. 151). The device by 
which this object is accomplished is known as the “blended 
price” (Joint App. 151). The Order provides for fixing 
minimum prices for Class I and Class II milk to be paid by 
the distributors, who purchase from the farmers and who 
are generally known as “handlers” (Joint App. 151). Each 
handler pays for the milk that he receives. The Market 
Administrator, however, computes, on the basis of the 
minimum prices, the value of all milk sold in the area each 
month and, after making certain adjustments prescribed by 
the Order, calculates a weighted average price, or “blended 
price”, as it is called (Joint App. 151). Each producer is 
paid on the basis of the blended price, subject again to 
certain adjustments (Joint App. 151). 

Before the blended price is computed, however, the Ad¬ 
ministrator is required to make a deduction prescribed by 
the Order and to pay the amount so deducted to those pro¬ 
ducers that are cooperative associations of dairymen 
(Joint App. 151). No similar payment is made to other 
producers (Joint App. 151). Provision for this deduction 
for cooperative payments was introduced into Order No. 4 
as amended for the first time bv the amendment effective 
on August 1, 1941 (Joint App. 151). In promulgating this 
amendment the Secretary made the following finding: 

“. . . that the provisions relating to the payments out 
of the equalization pool to cooperative associations per¬ 
forming certain marketing services are incidental to, 
not inconsistent with, the other provisions of the order, 
as amended, and necessary to effectuate the other pro¬ 
visions of the order, as amended.” (Joint App. 150- 
151). 


3 


The provisions with respect to cooperative payments, and 
the accompanying deduction from producer prices, have 
remained in Order No. 4 as amended from August 1, 1941 
down to the present time (Joint App. 152). Slight pro¬ 
cedural changes have been made in them. The Secretary’s 
original finding has never been amplified or amended (Joint 
App. 152). The sums of money paid to the cooperative 
associations under the Order have averaged approximately 
one-quarter of a million dollars each year (Joint App. 152). 
Equivalent amounts have been deducted in the computation 
of the minimum price to producers (Joint App. 152). 

The producer plaintiffs who instituted this action were 
non-members of cooperative associations and had been de¬ 
livering milk to the Boston market for many years (Joint 
App. 152). From 1941 down to the present time they have 
made substantial deliveries of milk to handlers under the 
Boston Order (Joint App. 153). They have an individual 
interest in the sums deducted from their prices for pay¬ 
ments to cooperative associations. The deductions for these 
payments have applied to their deliveries at rates ranging 
from 1-2/10 cents per hundredweight to 2-2/10 cents per 
hundredweight (Joint App. 153). 

For at least a quarter of a century there has been in effect 
in certain milk markets in the United States a system 
known as “the base rating plan” (Joint App. 153). Under 
this system each producer receives a base or quota predi¬ 
cated on the amount of his deliveries during a previous 
representative period of time. For so much of his current 
deliveries as are within this base or quota, he is paid a 
higher price than that applicable to his deliveries in excess 
of the quota. The base rating plan is entirely unrelated to 
any plan for payments to cooperative associations out of 
the equalization fund (Joint App. 153). 

In order to qualify for the contested payments the Order 
requires that a cooperative association be of the character 




4 


and perform the services which are specifically prescribed in 
the following terms: 

(1) It conforms to the requirements relating to char¬ 
acter of organization, voting, dividend payments, and 
dealing in products of nonmembers, which are set forth 
in the Capper-Volstead Act and in the state laws under 
which the association is organized. 

(2) It operates as a responsible producer-controlled 
marketing association exercising full authority in the 
sale of the milk of its members. 

(3) It systematically checks the weights and tests of 
milk which its members deliver to plants not operated 
by the association. 

(4) It guarantees payment to its members for milk 
delivered to plants not operated by the association. 

(5) It maintains, either individually or together with 
other qualified associations, a competent staff for deal¬ 
ing with marketing problems and for providing infor¬ 
mation to its members. 

(6) It constantly maintains close working relation¬ 
ships with its members. 

(7) It collaborates with similar associations in ac¬ 
tivities incident to the maintenance and strengthening 
of collective bargaining by producers and the operation 
of a plan of uniform pricing of milk to handlers. 

(S) It is in compliance with all applicable provisions 
of this order. 

(7 CFR 904.10(a) (1-8); substantially similar provi¬ 
sions were included in Order Xo. 4, as amended August 
1, 1941, 7 CFR 904.9(a) (1941 Supp.)). 

In its statement of the case, appellant refers to the co¬ 
operative payments as being made for “services rendered 
to the market as a whole” and “market-wide services” 
(Appellant’s Brief, p. 3,4). This is a serious and confusing 
inaccuracy. Under the Order, the qualifying services of a 
cooperative are primarily, and almost exclusively, “to its 
members ’\ a phrase which the Order repeatedly uses to 



5 


describe them. The Secretary’s finding does not describe 
them as “market-wide services”. Neither does the com¬ 
plaint. The Order does not call for performance by a co¬ 
operative of such activities as handling surplus milk, or 
supplying fluid milk to proprietary handlers, or substantial 
advertising, which the appellant relies on to justify the 
payments (Appellant’s Brief pages 12-22). 

Statements by the intervenor-appellant (pages 7-11 of its 
Brief) with respect to the appellees’ interest in the litiga¬ 
tion are not warranted by the evidence (Joint App. 254- 
363). This subject matter however constitutes a side issue 
injected into the Appellate Record by the intervenor appel¬ 
lant. Similar charges were deliberately withdrawn by the 
Secretary of Agriculture by appropriate action in the lower 
Court (Joint App. 466). We reserve an accurate statement 
of the testimony on this point to pages 37-40 infra, where 
we discuss the materiality of this issue. 

SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT. 

Section 8c(5) [U.S.C., Title 7, $608c(5)] lists the terms 
and conditions which may be included in milk orders under 
the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937,* Re¬ 
enacting, Amending and Supplementing the Agricultural 
Adjustment Act as amended. It opens with the declaration 
that orders “shall contain one or more of ... the terms and 
conditions” which are enumerated, and, except for the cate¬ 
gory next mentioned, “no others.” The Secretary is au¬ 
thorized to insert other terms and conditions which meet 
three prerequisites — they must “be incidental to, and not 
inconsistent with, the terms and conditions specified” and 
necessary to effectuate the other provisions of an order 
[Sec. 8c(7) (D), U.S.C., Title 7, $608c(7)(D)] 

The deduction from producer prices for cooperative pay¬ 
ments, provided for in the Boston milk order, is not one of 
the terms enumerated in Section 8c(5) of the Act. The 

•Act of June 3, 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 246, U.S.C., Title 7, § 601 
et seq. Relevant sections of the Act are set out in the Appendix to 
the Appellant’s Brief. 





6 


Statute permits the classifying of milk in accordance with 
its use and the fixing of minimum prices for each use 
classification [Sec. Sc(5)(A)]. These are the prices which 
handlers are required to pay. They are subject only to spe¬ 
cifically enumerated price adjustments. The next permis¬ 
sible statutory term [Sec. 8c(5)(B)] permits alternate 
methods of distributing the total dollar value of milk, fixed 
at the classified prices, among producers and associations 
of producers. The producer’s uniform or blended price 
may be computed on the basis of the utilization of all milk 
received by the particular handler to w 7 hom it is delivered 
[Sc(5)(B)(i)] or on the basis of the market-wide util¬ 
ization of milk by all handlers [Sc(5) (B) (ii)]. In either 
event, the price to the producer is subject “only” to spe¬ 
cific adjustments. The deduction for cooperative payments 
is not one of these adjustments. It is also not authorized 
by any of the remaining terms and conditions specified in 
Section 8c(5). 

The deduction for cooperative payments is not incidental 
to the prescribed statutory terms. A proper construction 
of the Act, in the light of its history, shows that the Secre¬ 
tary, as an incident of his power to fix prices, does not have 
the right to subtract a portion of the price in order to make 
large financial grants to cooperative associations, thereby 
depriving producers of a portion of the price fixed for their 
product, and forcing non-member producers to contribute to 
the resources of private associations to -which they do not 
belong. In the prescribed substantive terms of a milk order, 
Congress has treated as major matters of policy worthy of 
express legislative mandate: (1) the computation of the pro¬ 
ducer’s milk price and all permissible adjustments therein, 
(2) the specific marketing services for which deductions are 
appropriate from the price to those producers who are non¬ 
members of cooperatives, and (3) the rights and privileges 
to be accorded cooperative associations. The Secretary may 
not, in the guise of implementing these prescribed terms 


7 


with incidental and auxiliary provisions, add a new type of 
price adjustment to those specified by the legislature, deduct 
sums from non-member producers for marketing services 
by cooperatives to their own members, and dissipate the 
producer settlement fund, created for all practical purposes 
as a trust for producers, in novel bounties to cooperative 
associations. 

The deduction for cooperative payments is not consistent 
with the prescribed statutory terms. It is an adjustment in 
the price which is not included among the “only” adjust¬ 
ments permitted by Section 8c(5)(B). The permissible 
adjustments include those made by deduction from the total 
value of the pooled milk in the process of computing the 
uniform price. The statute does not proscribe only un¬ 
specified adjustments to the blended price after computa¬ 
tion. The cooperative payment deduction is also inconsistent 
with the provisions of Sec. 8c(5)(E) which cover the field 
of service deductions from non-member producers and spe¬ 
cify the marketing services for which such deductions can 
be made. This term of the Act does not allow a deduction 
from non-member producers for the purpose of compen¬ 
sating cooperatives for rendering the specified marketing 
services to their own members. As written in the Order, 
the deduction for cooperative payments has this effect. As 
now rationalized by the appellant, it still violates paragraph 
(E), which does not permit a deduction from the price to 
non-member producers on account of alleged “market¬ 
wide” services outside the scope of the specified market¬ 
ing services enumerated in the Act. 

It is necessary to keep steadily in mind that the services 
which cooperatives are required to perform are specifically 
enumerated in the Order (7 C.F.R. 904.10(a) (1-8), page 3, 
4 supra); that the services, so specified, are primarily and 
almost exclusively services by cooperatives to their own 
members; and, that it was the provision for payment for 
these services which the Secretary found to be incidental 





8 


to, and not inconsistent with, the other provisions of the 
Order as amended, and necessary to effectuate the same. 
To take money from non-member producers to pay coopera¬ 
tives for services to their own members is so indefensible 
that the appellant does not attempt to justify such a measure 
under the Act. It therefore tries to inject into the case, as 
a broader basis for the payments, other and different “mar¬ 
ket wide” services, despite the fact that these alleged serv¬ 
ices have never been made the basis for the contested 
payments in any official finding accompanying the promul¬ 
gation or amendment of the contested provisions of the 
Order, and have never been required by the Order itself. 
The affidavits in the Record setting forth these alleged mar¬ 
ket wide services (Joint App. 14, 60, 77) were not sub¬ 
mitted by appellant to Judge Holtzoff at the hearing on the 
merits.* 

The appellees maintain that the cooperative payment de¬ 
duction is not authorized by the Act, regardless of whether 
it rests on the services prescribed by the Order, or upon 
other and different “services” of the character now relied 
on to support it. Our argument, as thus far outlined, applies 
to the deduction whether it is considered as written in the 
Order or as now rationalized in the appellant’s argument. 
There is nothing in contemporaneous legislation, subsequent 
legislative history, or other provisions of the Act to support 
its validity. In determining its invalidity the District 
Court (S2 F. Supp. 614; Joint App. 142-150) correctly ap¬ 
plied applicable rules of law governing the scope of judicial 
review, and addressed itself to the precise question of law 
which the Supreme Court considered was at issue. Stark v. 
Wickard, 321 U.S. 288, 307, 311. The appellees’ standing to 
sue has already been adjudicated by that tribunal, and the 
intervenor’s charges of champerty and maintenance are 
frivolous. 

•These affidavits were printed in the Joint Appendix upon ap¬ 
pellant’s insistenee, and over appellees’ objection, presumably on 
the theory that the appeal carries with it orders overruling mo¬ 
tions for summary judgment, which are ordinarily not appealable. 
(See 3 Moore’s Federal Practice (1938) § 56.09). 




9 


L 

The contested provisions are not authorised by, and are not 
“incidental to ”, any of the terms of a milk order prescribed 
in Section 8c(5).* 

The term authorized in paragraph (A) of Section Sc(5) 
permits the classifying of milk in accordance with its use 
and the fixing of minimum prices for each use classification. 
Paragraph (B) authorizes the payment to producers of a 
uniform price computed on the basis of the use of all the 
milk delivered to a particular handler or on the basis of the 
market-wide utilization of milk by all handlers. The uni¬ 
form class prices are “subject only to adjustment for (1) 
volume, market, and production differentials customarily 
applied by the handlers subject to such order, (2) the grade 
or quality of the milk purchased and (3) the locations at 
which delivery of such milk, or any use classification thereof, 
is made to such handlers.” These are likewise the “only” 
adjustments in the producers’ uniform or blended price 
permitted by Paragraph (B) of Section 8c(5), with one 
addition. Paragraph (B) also allows: 

“(d) a further adjustment, equitably to apportion 
the total value of the milk purchased by any handler, 
or by all handlers, among producers and associations 
of producers, on the basis of their marketings of milk 
during a representative period of time.” 

The permissible price adjustments set forth in the Act 
were explained by both the Senate and House Committees 
reporting on the bill which amended the Agricultural Ad¬ 
justment Act in 1935 and enacted present Section 8c(5). 
The House Committee on Agriculture made the following 
statement (74th Congress, 1st Session, House Report No. 
1241, pages 9-10): 

“ Minimum prices fixed in such orders are required to 
be uniform as to all handlers, subject to adjustments for 


•U.S.C., Title 7, § 608c(5). 






10 


differences in the grade and quality of the milk deliver¬ 
ed, for differences in transportation costs from the place 
at which delivery is made to the handler to the distribut¬ 
ing or processing plant, and for volume, market, and 
production differentials customarily applied by hand¬ 
lers. The volume differential is a differential which is 
paid when the operations of several country plants 
are consolidated into one plant. The inconvenience 
which is caused to producers by closing up plants to 
which they have been delivering and requiring that 
all of their milk be handled by one plant, is compen¬ 
sated by an additional payment to the producers. The 
production differential is the differential which is paid 
to a producer, compensating him for keeping his farm 
and milk qualified for a city market even though his 
milk may actually be going into manufactured use. 
It is necessary to keep this supply of reserve milk 
available for periods in which consumption of milk 
goes up so that the effect is that the producers must 
keep their farm in the same condition as if they were 
shipping milk into the city every day. The production 
differential is a payment to the farmer for performing 
this function in the market. 

‘‘The market differential is a differential which is 
given to the producer to compensate him for deliver¬ 
ing his milk to a city market instead of to a country 
plant. These differentials vary with the markets and 
cannot be qualified as a ‘location’ differential, because 
of the fact that location is usually determined on the 
distance from a primary market whereas market differ¬ 
entials are usually paid in secondary markets.” 

The Senate Report was to the same effect (74th Congress, 
1st Session, S. Report Xo. 1011, p. 9-10). There is no claim 
by either appellant that the deduction for cooperative pay¬ 
ments comes within the permitted price adjustments for 
volume, market and production differentials, or that it is 
an adjustment relating to quality or location. 



11 


As in the case of the other price adjustments, Congress 
made clear the purpose of the “further adjustment” per¬ 
mitted by paragraph (B). 

“In order to eliminate, so far as possible, violent 
seasonal fluctuations in the available milk supply with 
their attendant disturbing effect upon returns to pro¬ 
ducers, and to encourage a uniform volume of produc¬ 
tion throughout the year, an adjustment in payments 
to producers upon the basis of their production records 
during a representative period may be included in such 
orders ...” (Senate Report No. 1011 (p. 11) and House 
Report No. 1241 (p. 10) 74th Congress, First Session).* 

In accordance with the expressed intent of Congress, the 
language of subparagraph (d) of 8c(5)(B) exactly fits the 
“base rating plan” as that plan is described by the Court 
below in paragraph 6 of its Findings of Fact (Joint App. 
153; p. 3, supra).** 

The cooperative payment provisions do not purport to 
apportion “the total value of milk”, or to have any rela¬ 
tionship to marketings of milk “during a representative 
period of time.” It is impossible to bring them within this 
statutory language authorizing the “entirely unrelated” 

* As first enacted in 1935, the clause under discussion read “on 
the basis of their production of milk during a representative 
period of time” (Act of August 24, 1935; ch. 641, Sec. 5, 49 Stat. 
753). When the provision was amended and reenacted as the 
Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, the word ‘pro¬ 
duction’ was changed to ‘marketing’ so as to avoid any implication 
of the production control denounced in United States v. Butler, 
297 U.S. 1 (1936) (House Report No. 468, 75th Congress, First 
Session). 

The Court’s description of the base rating plan is in accord 
with official publications of the Department of Agriculture (“Sta¬ 
bility of Milk Markets” IT. S. Dept, of Agriculture Marketing In¬ 
formation Series D.M. (3) 1938; p. 12, Plaintiffs’ Exhibit No. 1, 
in the District. Court; “Base Allotments or Quota Plans used by 
Farmer’s Cooperative Milk Associations”, Farm Credit Adm. U. S. 
Dept, of Agriculture M. R. No. 23, May 1940, p. 2-3, Plaintiffs’ 
Exhibit No. 2 in the District Court). 





12 


base rating plan (Joint App. 153). Indeed, the intervenor- 
appellant concedes that the further adjustment authorized 
by subparagraph (d) “probably relates to what is com¬ 
monly known as ‘base rating’ plan” (Intervenor-Appel¬ 
lant's Brief, p. 30). In the District Court the appellant 
disclaimed any reliance on this provision as authority for 
the deduction here in issue (Official Transcript of Proceed¬ 
ings before Judge Holtzoff, p. 18, 19). In reversing its 
position in this Court, the appellant takes three words of 
the provision—“equitably to apportion”—out of their con¬ 
text, and ignores the balance of the pertinent statutory 
language which describes the base rating plan (Appellant’s 
Brief, p. 27). 

We have shown that the deduction for cooperative pay¬ 
ments does not come within any of the price adjustments 
specified in paragraphs (A) and (B) of Section 8c(5). 
There is no claim by either appellant that such a reduction 
is authorized by any other term of a milk order enumerated 
in that Section. Paragraph (E) authorizes a price deduc¬ 
tion for certain marketing services rendered to producers 
not receiving such services from cooperative associations. 
Neither appellant relies on this provision, and, as we shall 
later point out, the challenged deduction is not consistent 
with it. 

If the deduction for cooperative payments is not ex¬ 
pressly authorized by any of the terms prescribed in Section 
Sc(5), the question arises as to whether it is incidental to 
them. As to this, the District Court held that the contested 
provisions were not incidental to the authorized terms set 
forth in Section 8c(5) but were “entirely independent and 
of major importance” (Joint App. 148). A proper con¬ 
struction of the Act in relation to these provisions supports 
the conclusion of the District Court. 

In the first place, the Act itself shows very clearly the 
type of subject matter which Congress placed in the cate¬ 
gory of the prescribed provisions of a milk order and 





13 


outside the scope of any discretionary power in the Secre¬ 
tary. Adjustments and deductions affecting the computa¬ 
tion of the uniform price to producers were set forth in 
minute detail. Congressional committees, as we have seen, 
were at pains to explain the meaning of the allowed 
“location”, “volume”, “market” and “production” differ¬ 
entials. That which touched the computation of the 
farmer’s milk check was a matter for express prescription 
by the legislator. 

Congress did not consider the rendering of services to 
producers not served by cooperatives, and the making of 
appropriate price deductions therefor, as an “incidental” 
term of a milk order. It dealt with this subject with the 
utmost particularization, carefully describing the services, 
as a substantive term of a milk order, in Section 8c(5)(E). 

Neither did Congress consider the privileges and rights 
to be accorded cooperative associations under a milk order 
as an incidental matter. Again, it dealt with this subject 
carefully and explicitly as a substantive matter in Section 
8c(5)(F). The Act is replete with other instances where 
the rights and privileges of cooperatives were spelled out in 
detail (See U.S.C., Title 7, §§ 60Sc(12) and 610(b) (1)). 

In each instance when Congress dealt with (a) deductions 
from producer prices, (b) marketing services to non¬ 
member producers and (c) the rights and privileges of co¬ 
operatives, it did not treat these subjects as incidental 
features of an order falling within the ambit of administra¬ 
tive discretion. They were placed in the category of the 
prescribed major terms of an order. They were put in the 
realm of primary things, not made to pertain to other pro¬ 
visions and not designed to be auxiliary to terms otherwise 
specified. 

Congress similarly explicitly prescribed authorized pro¬ 
grams relating to the problems of the creation or disposal 
of a surplus of any commodity. With respect to commodi- 




14 


ties other than milk, it specifically authorized provisions in 
an order, “determining the existence and extent of the 
surplus . . . , providing for the control and disposition of 
such surplus, and for equalizing the burden of such surplus 
elimination or control among the producers and handlers 
thereof” (U.S.C., Title 7, ^6080(6) (D)), and also made spe¬ 
cific provision for the rendering of the service of maintain¬ 
ing reserve supplies (U.S.C., Title 7, $608c(6) (E)). Signifi¬ 
cantly, no such terms were authorized for inclusion in orders 
regulating milk. 

Congress was not oblivious of the seasonal surplus in 
milk production. It sought to “eliminate, so far as pos¬ 
sible, violent seasonal fluctuations in the available milk 
supply” by “encouraging a uniform volume of produc¬ 
tion throughout the year”, and, to this end, specifically 
authorized a price adjustment under the familiar “base 
rating plan” (House Report No. 1241, 74th Congress, 1st 
Session, p. 10). It prevented “assaults upon the price 
structure by the sporadic importation of milk from new 
producing areas” by an authorized term limiting the price 
to new producers for ninety days to that fixed for manu¬ 
factured milk (House Report No. 1241, p. 11; Sec. 8c(5) 
(D)). Apart from these provisions, the problem of surplus 
milk was handled through the vehicle of the authorized 
term permitting market-wide equalization, and a blended 
price to each producer computed on the basis of the entire 
surplus in the market (Sec. 8c(5)(B)). With respect to 
commodities other than milk, Congress considered that 
“the chief obstacle to the attainment of the declared policy 
is the existence of market supplies far in excess of quantities 
sufficient to meet an effective consumer demand” (House 
Report No. 1241, p. 11). With respect to milk and its 
products, Congress considered surplus to be a seasonal 
factor. In both cases, however, Congress placed appro¬ 
priate and carefully considered programs for dealing with 
the problem of surplus within the specifically enumerated 
terms of orders. Even the method of paying expenses in¬ 
curred in carrying out such authorized programs was not 




15 


left to any “incidental” power of the Secretary, but was 
explicitly provided for by the Statute (U.S.C., Title 7, $610 
(b)(2)). 

The pertinent legislative history further shows that the 
basic provisions of the Act were passed in 1935 with a clear 
intention, demonstrated in the Congressional debates and re¬ 
ports, to delegate only very limited powers to the Secretary 
of Agriculture (79th Cong. Rec. 9461-9462, 9480). During 
the process of the legislative evolution of the provisions of 
this Statute, the Supreme Court decided the Schechter case 
(Schechter v. United States , 295 U.S. 495), invalidating 
provisions of the National Industrial Recovery Act because 
of the failure of Congress to prescribe therein the powers 
granted to the administrative authority. Pending bills to 
supplement and amend the Agricultural Adjustment Act 
were thereupon revised. H.R. 8492, the substantial form in 
which the legislation passed Congress, finally emerged from 
the Committee as the product of this process of revision. 
In this process, precise delegation of legislative authority 
to avoid the ban of the Schechter case was the dominant 
Congressional consideration. As the Chairman of the 
House Committee on Agriculture which reported the bill 
said on the Floor (79 Cong. Rec. 9461) : 

“We have undertaken to set out specifically just 
what these orders may and may not contain, thus fur¬ 
nishing a definite yardstick to guide the Department 
of Agriculture in making out the program under these 
‘orders’.” 

Other Committee members joined in expressing this inten¬ 
tion. It appears clearly in the Report of the House Com¬ 
mittee accompanying H.R. 8492 (House of Representatives, 
74th Congress, 1st Session, Report No. 1241, June 15, 
1945). The Senate report on the same legislation states: 

“To eliminate questions of improper delegation of 
legislative authority raised by the decision in Schechter 





16 


et al v. United States, the provisions relating to orders 
enumerate the commodities to which orders issued by 
the Secretary of Agriculture may be applicable, pre¬ 
scribe fully the administrative procedure to be fol¬ 
lowed by the Secretary in issuing, enforcing and termi¬ 
nating orders, and specify the terms which may be 
included in orders dealing with the enumerated com¬ 
modities." (74th Congress, 1st Session, May 3, 1935) 
(Calendar Day July 13) (italics supplied). 

In the Rock Royal case, 307 U. S. 533, 575, the Supreme 
Court recognized the intent of Congress to prescribe limits 
in the Act to administrative action. The Court said: 

“Here the terms of orders are limited to the specific 
provisions, minutely set out in Sc(5) and (7). While 
considerable flexibility is provided by 8c(7)(D), it 
gives opportunity only to include provisions auxiliary 
to these definitely specified.” 

In the Appellant’s view, matters which the Act expressly 
prohibits are the only provisions “which, as a matter of law, 
cannot be included under the incidental and necessary au¬ 
thorization in Sec. Sc(7)(D) of the Act” (Appellant’s 
Brief, p. 2S). This construction is very clearly opposed to 
that of the Supreme Court, limiting the authority of Section 
Sc(7)(D) “only to include provisions auxiliary to those 
definitely specified.” The Court below followed the Su¬ 
preme Court in refusing to accept the appellant’s extreme 
view of his administrative powers. In entire harmony with 
the legislative history of the Act, as well as the normal and 
accepted meaning of the language used in Section Sc (7) (D), 
the District Court said: 

“. . . The word ‘incidental’ means minor, auxiliary, or 
subordinate to a principal or primary subject. A thing 
incidental to an express provision is dependent or an¬ 
cillary to it. The term does not comprehend something 
additional to and independent of the principal subject 
matter. It relates solely to matters of a subordinate 
nature inherently forming a part and parcel of the main 
topics.” (Joint App. 147). 




17 


And the District Court held: 

“A provision for making substantial deductions from 
the equalization pool and paying them to cooperative 
associations can hardly be construed as incidental to the 
other parts of the Order. It is entirely independent and 
is of major importance.” (Joint App. 148). 

There is certainly nothing incidental about the economic 
impact of the contested provisions. The sums of money 
taken from producers and paid to cooperative associations 
under the Boston Order have averaged one-quarter of a 
million dollars each year (Joint App. 152). The deduction 
has been “a burden on every area sale”, as the Supreme 
Court earlier characterized it. Stark v. Wickard, 321, U.S. 
288, 303. In the Boston market it has already transferred 
over one and a half million dollars to cooperative associa¬ 
tions in deductions from producers’ milk prices. Milk pro¬ 
ducers are thereby made enforced contributors to the re¬ 
sources of private associations to which they do not belong. 

Viewed under every pertinent aspect, the cooperative 
payment provision departs from the nature of an “inci¬ 
dental” term. It creates a new price adjustment, although 
the Act carefully prescribes the only allowable price adjust¬ 
ments in the enumerated terms. It provides for a novel 
money bounty to cooperative associations, although the Act 
spells out cooperative rights and privileges. Despite the 
fact that the Act expressly prescribes, in the enumerated 
terms, the precise services to non-member producers for 
which a price deduction may be made, the cooperative pay¬ 
ment deduction is predicated upon an entirely different 
category of alleged services to non-member producers. 
Although the Act specifically places programs for dealing 
with the problem of surplus in the realm of its major and 
express authorized terms, the Appellant now rationalizes 
the contested deduction as a program related to the main¬ 
tenance and disposition of surplus milk supplies. 



18 


The Secretary’s original and only statutory finding did 
not specify any particular provision of the Act or Order 
to which the cooperative payment deduction was incidental. 
Indeed, at various times officials of the Department of Agri¬ 
culture have indicated that the deduction was originally 
promulgated in reliance on a truncated portion of the lan¬ 
guage of Section 8c(5) (B) (ii) (d) authorizing the base 
rating adjustment, rather than as an incidental term under 
Section Sc(7)(D) (See Joint App. 28, 96-97; 9 F.R. 3057- 
3060 (1944)). The appellant currently furnishes as the 
primary rationale of the contested provisions the alleged 
“market-wide” services of cooperative associations in 
maintaining a reserve supply of milk, with attendant sales 
of fluid milk to proprietary handlers in the short season, and 
the maintenance of facilities for manufacturing surplus 
milk in the flush season (Appellant’s Brief, p. 12-20). 

In the first place, Order No. 4 as amended does not re¬ 
quire that cooperatives process surplus or sell milk in short 
supply as conditions for the receipt of the payments here in 
issue, which are made upon the basis of other and quite 
distinct activities and functions (7 C.F.R. 904.10(a) (1-8), 
set out on pp. 3-4, supra). Manifestly the Order does not en¬ 
courage the rendition of services which it fails even to men¬ 
tion. Indeed, if services not mentioned or required by the 
Order supply the rational link between provisions for co¬ 
operative payments and the Act, it must follow that the 
actual provisions of Order No. 4 are far removed from 
statutory sanction. 

In the second place, there is an important feature of the 
manufacture of surplus and the sale of fluid milk in short 
supply to which the appellant never adverts, although the 
record in this case manifests it clearly. These activities 
are business operations carried on by handlers whether 
cooperative or proprietary, voluntarily, and for profit. 
Handlers can and do recover in the normal channels of 
trade, through the prices charged in selling fluid milk, the 


19 


cost of any alleged service in maintaining a standby supply 
of milk. Indeed the manufacturing operation itself may 
be more profitable at times than the disposition of milk in 
fluid form.* Certainly payments to handlers for engaging 
in self supporting and even profitable business operations 
constitute a pure subsidy, neither incidental or necessary 
to any provision of the Act or Order. With an obvious 
recognition of these factors, the appellant’s representative 
and economist (Joint App. 14) suggested at the original 
hearing that any payments to cooperatives must be sur¬ 
rounded with certain “necessary” conditions: they must 
sell milk to other handlers at the Class I price without a 
premium; maintain the availability of their supplies, free 
from the ties of long term contracts; and willingly accept 
all milk without a market (Joint App. 198, 199). However, 
the provisions of the Order were written with no such 
conditions attached to the receipt of payments. The co¬ 
operative associations receiving payments were free to 
and did charge premium prices on fluid milk sales to other 
handlers (Joint App. 92, 93, 94, 104, 374, 419). In practice, 
and under Order No. 4 as written, the cooperative pay¬ 
ments are stripped of any aspect of compensation for the 
performance of a service function to other handlers or 
to the market. 

* See frank statement by witness Thompson (Joint App. 200) 
“... We want to stand ready to supply fluid milk. I am not trying 
to represent that our motives in that respect are entirely benevo¬ 
lent. They are in the interest of our members ...” (See Joint 
App. 38, 39). There has never been any provision of law fixing or 
regulating the maximum price which cooperatives might charge 
for milk sold by them to other handlers, or for services rendered in 
connection with such sales (Request for Admission of Facts #7, 
Joint App. 92, 93). Cooperatives have exacted premiums over 
the Class I price in selling fluid milk to other handlers (Joint App. 
38, 104, 374, 419). As to the manufacturing of surplus, the ap¬ 
pellant states (Brief p. 15), “In some instances, it may be more 
profitable to the handler, although not more profitable to the pro¬ 
ducers. to utilize the milk in a lower class.” (See also Joint App. 
38, 39). 



20 


Finally, even if the cooperative payment provisions of 
the Order were recast to require the activities now relied 
on to support them, and to contain the necessary conditions 
suggested by the Secretary’s representative at the original 
hearing, they would still fall outside the scope of an “inci¬ 
dental term” under the Act. For even thus recast in a new 
and different form they would represent an attempt by 
the Secretary to use his power to fix and equalize producer 
prices as a means of granting funds to support those 
factors which he deems to be stabilizing and helpful in the 
marketing of milk. Congress has given him no such power 
under this Act. As the District Court said: 

“ . . . No doubt the Congress, if it chose to do so, 
might have granted subsidies to them (cooperatives) 
out of public moneys. Conceivably, it might possibly 
have provided that subventions should be paid to them 
out of the common fund created under the Milk Orders. 
The Congress has, however, done neither. An officer 
of the Executive branch of the Government, by an 
administrative order, has directed that out of the pool 
belonging in equity to all of the milk producers, a 
certain amount should be deducted and paid to coopera¬ 
tive associations, thus depriving the remaining pro¬ 
ducers of a portion of the money that would otherwise 
be paid to them. Obviously, no matter how well in¬ 
tended, or even how desirable his action might be, an 
Executive officer of the Government may not overstep 
the statutory limitations on his authority. He may 
not take the property of one person and give it to an¬ 
other.” (Joint App. 147). 

There are no doubt a variety of activities which stabilize 
milk markets and inure to the benefit of producers, hand¬ 
lers and consumers. The dealer who expands the consumer 
demand for fluid milk by an aggressive sales policy, the 
Dairy Council which advertises milk and dairy products, 
the Dairy Herd Improvement Associations, the State Agri¬ 
cultural Colleges, all engage in activities which an honest 
administrator might determine on satisfactory evidence 


21 


have as helpful and fruitful an impact on the economic 
problems of the milk market and the dairy farmer as the 
appellant ascribes to the activities of cooperative asso¬ 
ciations. Whether these activities are entitled to extra¬ 
ordinary financial grants, and, if so, upon whom the burden 
of their support shall fall, are typically matters falling 
within the legislative domain. 

In the present Act Congress has granted the Secretary 
power to classify milk according to its use and to fix prices 
for milk in such use classification. The power to fix a price 
in accordance with statutory standards does not have as 
its incident the power to subtract from the price fixed in 
order to raise and disburse funds for public, or quasi-public 
purposes. The power to levy a sales tax (Stark v. Wickard, 
321 U.S. 288, 303) is not auxiliary to the power to fix a price. 
In State v. Dairy Distributors Inc., 217 Wis. 167, 258 
N. W. 383, the Supreme Court of Wisconsin considered the 
requirement of a State Milk Order that all dealers and 
producers should contribute one half cent per hundred 
pounds to the Milwaukee Dairy Council. The basic statute 
authorized, inter alia, the prescribing of price schedules 
at which milk or cream might be bought and sold, and gave 
the administrative Board power to carry out the provisions 
and intent of the Act and “to do all things reasonably 
necessary and convenient” in the exercise of that power. 
The Court held that the Order provisions for contribution 
to the Dairy Council were invalid. 

The Court said: 

“If the legislature intends to confer upon adminis¬ 
trative bodies the power not only to fix just and reason¬ 
able prices for milk and cream, but also the power to 
set up independent agencies for the promotion of the 
business aspects of the industry and compel all persons 
selling milk in the metropolitan area to contribute, that 
intent should be expressed in clear and unmistakable 




22 


terms. The exaction made is not in any way related 
to the expense of administering or enforcing the law, 
nor is it paid into the public treasury, nor is the agency 
to which it is paid required to make any accounting to 
the contributors to the fund. We shall not determine 
whether or not the legislature itself could make a valid 
enactment of like character because the question is not 
presented upon this record. It is clear that the legis¬ 
lature has attempted to confer no such power upon the 
commission by sec. 99.165.” 

In the present case, there is even less reason for finding 
in the power to fix prices an auxiliary power to finance the 
activities of private corporations in handling surplus milk. 
When Congress intended that the Secretary should pro¬ 
mulgate programs for the establishment of reserve supplies 
of commodities, it authorized them in “clear and unmis¬ 
takable terms” as major prescribed terms of an Order 
(U.S.C., Title 7, §608c(6) (E)). It also expressly authorized 
measures “for equalizing the burden of surplus elimination 
or control among producers and handlers” (U.S.C., Title 7, 
§60Sc(6) (D)). Significantly, it authorized such programs 
only with respect to “other commodities” than milk. As 
to milk, it regarded the surplus problem as seasonal and 
again expressly prescribed the measures it deemed appro¬ 
priate to meet this seasonality. These measures, carefully 
and explicitly authorized, were a price adjustment in favor 
of the producer who evened out his yearly production, a 
lower price for the market newcomer, and a blended price 
to all regular producers, reflecting the market surplus as 
it exists from time to time (Sec. 8c(5)(B) and 8c(5)(D)). 

The Secretary has devised an additional and different 
program directed to the problem of surplus milk and reserve 
supplies, which consists in subsidizing the processing and 
handling thereof. The wisdom of such a program is typically 
a matter of legislative judgment. In carrying it out, the 
Secretary has further decided that the onus of its financial 
support shall rest, not on handlers or consumers, but ex- 




23 


clusively on producers through a deduction in their milk 
prices. Here again he has arrogated to himself a legislative 
prerogative and decided the question quite differently from 
the only analogous pronouncement of the legislature. For, 
when Congress did expressly authorize measures “for 
equalizing the burden of surplus elimination or control”, 
in the case of other commodities, it was careful to specify 
that “handlers” as well as producers should share the 
burden, (U.S.C., Title 7, §608c(6) (D)). In effect, the Secre¬ 
tary has attempted to write a new substantive term into 
the Statute, with little regard to its harmony with existing 
statutory prescriptions. 

n. 

The cooperative payment provisions are inconsistent icith 
the terms of a Milk Order prescribed in Section 8c(5)(B) 
and (E). 

Section 8e(5)(B)* 

The District Court, in discussing the cooperative payment 
deduction, declared: 

“Moreover, the provision can hardly be said to be 
‘not inconsistent’ with the terms and conditions ex¬ 
pressly specified in the statute. The statute provides 
that the price shall be subject to adjustments only for 
enumerated factors. There is no provision for an ad¬ 
justment by way of a deduction in favor of cooperative 
associations.” (Joint App. 148). 

We submit that the District Court was correct, and that 
the cooperative payment adjustment is inconsistent with 
the express provisions of Section 8c(5)(B). 

Both appellants insist on attributing to the District Judge 
a failure to observe that the limitation in Section 8c(5) to 
the effect that a Milk Order shall contain enumerated terms 
and conditions and “no others” is qualified by the ex¬ 
ception for terms and conditions authorized under Section 
8c(7) (D) (Intervenor-Appellant’s Brief, p. 29; Appellant’s 
Brief, p. 26). The court’s opinion shows no such oversight. 


•U.S.C. Title 7, §608c(5)(B). 



24 


The appellant insists, however, that the exception in Section 
Sc(5) for an “incidental and necessary provision” under 
Section Sc(7)(D) permits a price adjustment “in addition 
to those in Section Sc(5) ” (Appellant's Brief, p. 26). It is 
the appellant who thereby “overlooks” pertinent statutory 
language. Section Sc(7) (D) requires that any term author¬ 
ized thereunder shall be “not inconsistent with the terms 
and conditions” specified in Section 8c(5). An incidental 
term which is inconsistent with the terms and conditions 
specified in Section Sc(5) has no entry into a Milk Order 
under Section Sc(7)(D). Section Sc(5)(B) expressly pro¬ 
vides that producer prices shall be subject “owZ?/” to speci¬ 
fied adjustments. Consequently, a provision for a further 
and unspecified adjustment is inconsistent with Section 
8c(5) (B) and, by that very token, unauthorized by Section 
Sc(7)(D). The District Court correctly held that a price 
adjustment by way of a deduction in favor of cooperatives 
was not among the only permissible price adjustments 
specified in Section 8c(5) (B). (See pages 9-12, supra, where 
the meaning of these adjustments is discussed). 

To escape the inconsistency inherent in the establishment 
of a price adjustment outside of those specified in Section 
8c(5)(B), the appellants argue that this provision of the 
Act applies only to adjustments to the blended price after 
it has been computed, not to adjustments by way of deduc¬ 
tions in the process of computation (Appellant’s Brief, pp. 
26-27; Intervenor-Appellant’s Brief, pp. 30-31). This argu¬ 
ment is based on an incorrect assumption. The inter- 
venor’s statement (Intervenor-Appellant’s Brief, p. 31) 
“All of the foregoing listed deductions are made after 
determination of the blended or pool price to be distributed 
to producers” is completely erroneous. Several of the 
authorized price adjustments such as the base rating ad¬ 
justment and those for grade, quality and location differ¬ 
entials are made in precisely the same manner as the co¬ 
operative payment deduction under the Boston Order as 
amended, viz, by subtraction from the total value of the 


25 


pooled milk prior to the final computation of the uniform 
price to producers.* The cooperative deduction could be 
accomplished, with less administrative convenience, by a 
subtraction from the final blended price payable to indi¬ 
vidual producers, as well as by the easier method used, of 
subtracting the total amount of the required payments in 
the computation of the blended price. The validity of the 
deduction can scarcely depend upon the mathematical 
process adopted. In any event, under the Act any distinc¬ 
tion between adjustments in the computation, and after the 
computation of the blended price is fanciful. The Act 
authorizes certain specific adjustments which the Secretary 
regularly carries out by deduction in the process of com¬ 
puting the price. It does not refer only to adjustments in 
the uniform price after its computation. 

# The provision of Orders which contain the base rating ad¬ 
justment shows that this adjustment is accomplished by a sub¬ 
traction from the total value of the pooled milk before a uniform 
price is computed (New Orleans Order, Sec. 942.7 (c), 14 F.R. 5960, 
5962 (1949), and Wichita Order, 7 C.F.R. 968.7(b)). See also 
“base rating” provisions as previouslv contained in the follow¬ 
ing Orders: Fall River, Mass., 7 C.F.R, 905.8(b)(2) (1938); 
Kansas City, 7 C.F.R. 913.8(b)(2) (1938); LaPorte County, In¬ 
diana, 7 C.F.R. 920.8(b) (2) (3) (1938), Quad Cities, 7 C.F.R. 
944.7(b) (2) (3) (4) (1940 Supp.). The appellant, in his Brief 
(p. 30) submitted to the District Judge, after describing the base 
rating adjustment, stated: “This differential is subtracted from 
the total use value of the milk in the pool before the blended 
price is calculated and results in one group of producers receiving 
a higher price for their milk because of the dependability of their 
supply.” The price adjustment for butterfat which is authorized 
as a grade or quality differential under Section 8c(5) (B) (ii) (b) 
may also be accomplished by a deduction from the value of the 
pooled milk before computation of the uniform price (See Quad 
Cities Order, 7 C.F.R. 944.7(b)(3), Davton-Springfield Order, 
7 C.F.R. 971.7(c)(4) and Minneapolis-St. Paul Order, 7 C.F.R. 
973.7(b)(2)). Several existing orders contain provisions for de¬ 
ductions from or additions to the use value of handlers’ milk of 
an amount equal to the total location differentials, which are also 
permissible adjustments to producers’ prices under the Act. This 
addition or subtraction is made before division by the total quan¬ 
tity of milk to determine the blended price to producers. (See 
Boston Order, 7 C.F.R. 904.8(b)(4) and Minneapolis-St. Paul 
Order, 7 C.F.R. 973.7(b)(1)). 




26 


Finally, in order to reconcile an unspecified price deduc¬ 
tion with the Act, the appellant contends that the Act con¬ 
tains no requirement “that the uniform prices to producers 
must reflect the total utilization of milk received by handlers 
and priced under the Order”, or “that the total amount 
paid to producers must equal the value of the milk pur¬ 
chased by handlers at the prices specified in the order” 
(Appellant’s Brief, pp. 26-27). On this theory, Congress 
has meticulously regulated adjustments in the prices hand¬ 
lers pay, and in the prices producers receive; but, having 
guarded the monetary value of the producer’s milk from 
unspecified diversions as the money comes in, and as it 
goes out, has left the fund entirely unprotected from un¬ 
specified diversions immediately after it comes in and 
immediately before it goes out. 

Such a contention undermines the whole purpose and 
integrity of the Act. It ignores the primary fact that the 
price fixing provisions of the Act provide for the payment 
“to producers'* of the prices payable for their product. 
The elaborate standards of the Act for the establishment 
of minimum classified prices become illusory if the pro¬ 
ducer’s price does not “reflect the total utilization of milk 
received by handlers and priced under the Order.” The 
Congressional Committee reporting on the provisions of 
Section Sc(5)(B) (i) and (ii) described them as furnishing 
“alternative methods of distributing the total dollar value 
of all milk sold in the market among the producers supply¬ 
ing the market ” (italics supplied) (House Report No. 1241, 
74th Congress, 1st Session, p. 10). In order to preclude 
any failure by producers to receive the full use value of 
the pooled milk. Congress expressly provided in Section 
8c(5)(C) for adjustments in payments among handlers “to 
the end that the total sums paid by such handler shall 
equal the value of the milk purchased by him at the prices 
fixed in accordance with paragraph (A) hereof” (italics 
supplied). Hence, both the language of the Statute as well 


27 


as the accompanying pertinent declaration of legislative 
intent directly repel the contention of the appellant that 
the Act does not require “that the total amount paid to 
producers must equal the value of the milk purchased by 
handlers at the prices specified in the Order.’’ Section 
8c(5)(C) authorizes the establishment of the “producer 
settlement” fund. The Order has always described pay¬ 
ments into that fund as payments “to the producer through 
the market administrator”. See Stark v. Wickard, 321 U.S. 
288, 301. As the Supreme Court has said in this case (321 
U.S. 288, 305): 

“The situation would be substantially the same if an 
administrator received as trustee for the producers 
the purchase price of their milk, paid expenses in¬ 
curred in the operation and paid the balance to the 
producers.” (italics supplied). 

and again (321 U.S. 288, 309): 

“The producer settlement fund is created to meet 
allowable deductions by the payment of a part of the 
minimum price to producers through the market ad¬ 
ministrator.” (italics supplied). 

The producer settlement fund is thus treated by the 
Supreme Court, for all practical purposes, as a trust fund 
for producers, created to insure that handlers pay to 
producers the full value of their milk at the classified prices 
subject only to allowable deductions. 

Section 8c(5)(E) # 

The deduction for cooperative payments is inconsistent with 
the provisions of Section 8c(5) (E) in the following respects: 

1. Paragraph (E) provides for a deduction from pro¬ 
ducer payments on account of the rendering to the producers 
from whom the deduction is made of enumerated services, 


•U.S.C., Title 7, § 608c(5) (E). 




28 


viz, market information, verification of weights, sampling 
and testing of milk. In the case of producers who are not 
members of cooperative associations, the Order authorizes 
a deduction, which is not only unrelated to the rendering 
to these producers of the services enumerated in the Act, 
but is used to make payments to cooperative associations 
who qualify for their receipt by rendering the enumerated 
services only to their own members. The Order requires 
that a cooperative association, receiving the payments, 
“check the weights and tests of milk which its members 
deliver” and maintain a staff “for providing information 
to its members ” (See 7 C.F.R. 904.10 (3) (5), page 3 supra). 

2. Paragraph (E) covers the field of service deductions 
from producers who are not members of cooperative asso¬ 
ciations. It permits only those deductions which are “ap¬ 
propriate” for the services which it enumerates. Hence, 
when the appellants contend that the cooperative pay¬ 
ments rest on the basis of certain “marketwide services” 
of cooperatives, such as handling surplus milk, making 
sales of fluid milk to proprietary handlers, testimony at 
public hearings, they treat the deduction as being made 
for functions distinctly different from those services enum¬ 
erated in the Act as the basis for appropriate deductions 
from the payments to non-member producers. 

3. The cooperative payment deduction distorts the ’whole 
purpose of Paragraph (E). That paragraph permits ap¬ 
propriate deductions for the services specified “except 
as to producers for whom such services are being rendered 
by a qualified cooperative”. Congress put cooperative 
members and non-members in distinct categories. For 
services rendered to members cooperatives may receive 
compensation through contract. Their full power to dis¬ 
tribute the proceeds of their sales in accordance with their 
contracts was protected by Paragraph (F) of Section 8c 


29 


(5). Congress undoutedly considered that cooperatives in 
practice did not render to non-member producers the 
marketing services which it enumerated, and authorized 
the Secretary to provide them. Prior to the insertion of 
the cooperative payment provision, the Order did provide 
for the rendition of these services by the Market Adminis¬ 
trator with an appropriate deduction from payments to non¬ 
members (7 C.F.R. 904.10 (1938)). The Market Adminis¬ 
trator is now required to furnish to producers, consumers 
and handlers “statistics and information concerning the 
operation of the Order” (7 C.F.R. 904.2 (d)(7)). The Or¬ 
der makes no other provision for furnishing to non-mem¬ 
ber producers the services specified in paragraph (E). The 
Secretary, acting on the assumption that he can deduct 
sums of money from payments to non-member producers 
to compensate cooperatives for services of a character not 
specified in the Act, actually requires the cooperatives to 
render services of the character specified in the Act only 
to their own members to qualify for the payment.* 

m. 

There is nothing in alleged contemporaneous legislation , 
subsequent legislative history, or other provisions of the Act 
to support the conclusion that the cooperative payment deduc¬ 
tion is authorized . 

We have previously discussed the legislative history of 
the pertinent statutory provisions (pp. 15-16, supra). We 
now examine extrinsic factors relied on by appellants as 
aids to construction. 


• The Secretary did not purport to find that the challenged de¬ 
duction was “not inconsistent” with the terms and conditions speci¬ 
fied in Section 8c(5). He merely found that the challenged provi¬ 
sions are incidental to and not inconsistent with “the other pro¬ 
visions of the order.” (See page 2, supra). As there is no term 
included in the Order pursuant to Section 8c(5)(E), the Secre¬ 
tary avoided any finding that the challenged provisions are not 
inconsistent with terms authorized by that paragraph. 



30 


1. Alleged “Contemporaneous Legislation”, (Inter- 
venor-Appellant’s Brief, pp. 39-42) 

New York did not authorize a deduction for cooperative 
payments until 1939 (Chap. 760, Laws of 1939). Such a 
deduction was not authorized by the New York statute effec¬ 
tive in 1937 (Chap. 383, Laws of 1937). The pertinent 
provisions of Section 8c (5) and (7) were enacted by Con¬ 
gress by amendment to the Agricultural Adjustment Act, 
approved August 24, 1935 (Act of Aug. 24, 1935, c. 641, § 5, 
49 Stat. 750, U.S.C., Title 7, § 60Sc(5),(7)) and were re¬ 
enacted with one slight change by the Agricultural Mar¬ 
keting Agreement Act of 1937 (Act of June 3, 1937, c. 296, 
§ 2, 50 Stat. 246). Obviously, Congress in 1935 could not 
have considered action in the New York legislature in 1939. 

2. Subsequent Legislative History. 

Both appellants argue that the legislative history of a 
Bill proposed in 1940 (S. 3426, 76th Congress, 3d Sess.) 
supports their construction of the Act. This bill, which 
would have authorized payments out of the producer settle¬ 
ment fund to cooperatives and other handlers, failed of 
passage, although the Secretary requested its enactment. 
Naturally, its proponents were guarded and self serving as 
to the Secretary’s existing powers, with the cooperative 
payments of the New York Order already challenged in 
the Courts. United Siates v. Rock Royal Cooperative , Inc., 
307 U. S. 533. The District Court realistically pointed out 
that “the Secretary must have had some doubt as to his 
power in the matter. Else he would not have asked for sup¬ 
plemental legislation expressly conferring such powers” 
(Joint App. 149-150). In any event, statements of the spon¬ 
sors of proposed amendatory legislation which fails do not 
indicate the intention of Congress in enacting the basic 
Statute years before. Indeed, the fact that a bill to amend 
fails of passage usually indicates legislative disapproval 
of its terms. Federal Trade Commission v. Bunte Bros., 




31 


312 U. S. 349, 352; Carey v. Donohue, 240 U. S. 430, 437. 
The terms of the proposed amendment also emphasized 
the inherent weakness of resting the contested provision on 
the Secretary’s “incidental” powers. It would have placed 
the authority for the contested payments with the other 
substantive terms in Section Sc(5)(C) and would have cre¬ 
ated some legislative standards regulating the nature of 
the services involved and handlers’ qualification for pay¬ 
ments. Despite the claims here asserted that these services 
are peculiar to cooperative associations, the proposed legis¬ 
lation would have permitted proprietary handlers to draw 
payments out of the pool for diverting surplus milk in 
periods of excess supply, and for furnishing fluid milk in 
times of insufficient supply. 

3. Section 10(b)(1) of the Agricultural Adjustment 
Act* 

This provision enjoins only such recognition and en¬ 
couragement of cooperative association “as will be in har¬ 
mony with the policy toward cooperative associations set 
forth in existing Acts of Congress”. There was, and is, no 
policy set forth in Acts of Congress favoring the support of 
cooperatives by enforced contributions from non-member 
producers, rather than by voluntary self help. Exemptions 
from anti-trust laws under the Clayton and Capper Vol¬ 
stead Acts and from the payment of Federal income taxes 
are a far cry from ‘ ‘ subventions out of the co mm on fund cre¬ 
ated under Milk Orders” (Joint App. 147). The policy of 
Congress has been to require equality of treatment for mem¬ 
bers and non-members. To require a non-member to be¬ 
come a member has been held to violate that equality of 

•Section 10(b)(1) of the Agricultural Adjustment Act was in¬ 
corporated into the Statute in 1935 (Act of Aug. 24, 1935, C. 641, 
§16, 49 Stat. 750, U.S.C., Title 7, §610(b) (1)) by way of amend¬ 
ment to the Agricultural Adjustment Act, (Act of May 12, 1933, 
c. 25, 48 Stat. 31) as previously amended. It was not expressly 
reenacted by the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 
(Act of June 3, 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 246). 



32 


treatment requisite to tax exemption. Farmer Union Coop. 
Supply Co. v. United States, 25 F. Supp. 93. A fortiori, 
Congress would not deem it equality of treatment to require 
a non-member to pay for cooperative activities as if he were 
a member. 

“There is nothing broadly eleemosynary in cooperative 
associations. They simply represent a banding together 
of producers for their common good, and the motive of each 
is pecuniary gain". Schuster v. Ohio Farmers’ Cooperative 
Milk Ass'n, 61 F. 2d 339. A requirement that non-member 
producers pay a portion of their milk price to these asso¬ 
ciations is a sweeping economic and social innovation. The 
intervenor’s diligence produced but one isolated and doubt¬ 
ful instance of the “check off" principle as applied to non¬ 
members in favor of cooperatives, in all the milk markets in 
the country prior to Federal Regulation; and even with the 
Secretary of Agriculture walling to sanction this principle, 
it was in operation in only four out of twenty-nine markets 
under Federal Orders in late 1946 (Joint App. 102). Had 
Congress wished to introduce the “check off" principle 
into milk marketing it would have done so in the specific 
language with which it granted other important privileges 
to cooperatives under the Act. (See U.S.C., Title 7, 
§§ 608c(5) (F), 608c(12), and 671). 

The legislative history of Section 10(b)(1) shows that it 
was intended to safeguard, rather than to enlarge, existing 
cooperative privileges. 

At the hearing before the Committee on Agriculture, 
House of Representatives, 74th Congress, First Session, on 
H. R. 55S5, February 26 to March 6,1935, Chester G. Davis, 
Administrator of the Agricultural Adjustment Act, testi¬ 
fied as follows respecting this provision (p. 16): 

“The inclusion of this language would make explicit 
the policy now being followed by the Agricultural Ad¬ 
justment Administration but would neither extend nor 
limit the authority of the Secretary." 




33 


Mr. Davis further testified as follows (p. 42): 

“Mr. Kleberg. It is not proposed, then, with the 
idea that there be any direction, under that definition, 
to give a subsidy in connection with the cooperatives as 
against the individual or the man on the outside? 

“Mr. Davis. Clearly not.” 

Mr. Davis testified to the same effect before the Senate 
Committee on Agriculture and Forestry, at hearings on S. 
1807, March 1935 (p. 44). 

The House Committee reporting on the provision under 
discussion made the following statement with regard there¬ 
to (74th Congress, 1st Session, H. R. 1241, p. 13): 

“It is not intended by this language to discriminate 
against other handlers, processors or dealers; but it 
has been found from experience that the participation 
by local committees and associations of producers has 
been of material value in administering the program. ’ ’ 
(italics supplied). 

In the Senate the sponsors of the measure assured that 
body that the provision in question was designed to leave 
intact the privileges and exemptions granted by law to 
cooperatives. Thus an express amendment to the provision 
in question forbidding discrimination against other pro¬ 
ducers, processors and handlers was represented to be un¬ 
necessary. The Senate was assured that no such discrimi¬ 
nation was involved, or contemplated by the law (79 Cong. 
Rec. 10927). 


IV. 

The District Court properly applied correct principles gov¬ 
erning the scope of judicial review in this case. 

The United States Supreme Court stated the issue in 
this case to be statutory power to make the deduction for 
cooperative payments, and left “the Trial Court free to 



34 


consider whether the statutory authority given the Secre¬ 
tary is a valid answer to the petitioner’s contention.” 
Stark v. Wickard, 321 U.S. 288, 307, 311. The District 
Court properly considered this precise issue. The Court 
evinced a proper respect for the Secretary’s discretionary 
powers, but correctly ruled (Joint App. 147): “The Secre¬ 
tary’s authority, however, is not unlimited and his discre¬ 
tion is not untrammelled. He must act w’ithin the confines 
and the orbit of the Statute.” An agency may not finally 
decide the limits of its statutory power. That is a judicial 
function. Social Security Board v. Nierotko, 327 U.S. 358, 
368-369. When it exceeds that power, no amount of ad¬ 
ministrative interpretation is binding upon the Courts. 
Texas & Pacific By. Co. v. United States, 289 U.S. 627, 640; 
Interstate Commerce Commission v. Cincinnati Str. Ry. Co., 
167 U.S. 479, 510. 

The Secretary’s finding was a general paraphrase of 
Sec. Sc(7)(D). There were no findings of ultimate facts 
or subsidiary facts. Their absence does not thwart judicial 
review. Whether the hearing record does or does not con¬ 
tain substantial evidence as to the market-wide services of 
cooperatives is not the focal point for argument. The 
Secretary found that the Order provisions for payments to 
cooperative associations “performing certain marketing 
services, were incidental to, not inconsistent with the other 
provisions of the Order and necessary . . . ” . He treated 
as immaterial evidence as to the alleged market-wide 
services now relied on to support the challenged provisions. 
The Order authorized the payments irrespective of the 
performance of such services. The basic issue, therefore, 
is whether the payments under the terms and conditions 
of the Order are authorized by the Act, not whether pay¬ 
ments made on some other set of conditions or for certain 
other services are permitted. The question of statutory 
authority for the actual Order provisions is precisely the 
type of question to which judicial review is properly di- 


35 


reeled and was, in fact, directed in this very case by the 
mandate of the Supreme Court. Even if the “ market- 
wide’ ’ services of cooperatives are germane to the issue, 
the case still presents a question of statutory power. For, 
assuming that the evidence in the hearing record as to 
“market-wide services” was substantial, the question still 
persists—does the Act authorize payments even for such 
services by a deduction from producer prices? 

The appellees maintain that, as a matter of law, the price 
deduction for cooperative payments is not authorized by 
the Act, regardless of whether the payments are treated 
as related to the services specified in the Order, or are 
related to the other and different services now relied on 
by the appellant. Under these circumstances, it is a super¬ 
ficial analysis of the appellees’ position to say that because 
they do not expressly attack the substantiality of the evi¬ 
dence before the Secretary, they are foreclosed on the 
question of statutory authority (See Appellant’s Brief, 
pp. 36-40). The appellees do not find it necessary to their 
argument to weigh the “pros” and “cons” of the testimony 
in the hearing record as to the alleged market-wide services 
of cooperatives. No quantum of evidence on this subject 
can transform into an “incidental” term an Order provi¬ 
sion which a proper construction of the Act demonstrates 
is not “incidental”, or make consistent with the Act a 
term which is inconsistent wdth it. Nor can an administra¬ 
tive official by the technique of paraphrasing the Act, a 
procedure which has not commended itself to this Court 
(see Saginaw Broadcasting Co. v. F.C.C ., 68 App. D.C. 
282, 96 F(2d) 554, 560) avoid judicial review of the legal 
conclusion, which on any possible factual hypothesis, is 
inherent in his finding. 

The appellees’ argument that current provisions of the 
Order are different from the original provisions, and hence 
the hearing record with respect to the Amendments of 
August 1, 1947 is germane, confuses the basic issues. The 






36 


Court below found as a fact (Joint App. 152): “The pro¬ 
visions with respect to cooperative payments, and the 
accompanying deduction from producer prices, have re¬ 
mained in Order No. 4 as amended from August 1, 1941 
down to the present time. Slight procedural changes have 
been made in them. On August 1, 1947 the rates of pay¬ 
ments were revised. The Secretary’s original finding has 
never been amplified or amended.”* ‘Manifestly subse¬ 
quent administrative hearing records pertinent only to 
“slight procedural changes” in the contested provisions, 
and giving rise to no new finding by the Secretary, would 
have no bearing on the essential issues in this litigation. 


V. 

The appellees have standing to sue, and the Intervenor- 
Appellant's charge of champerty and maintenance is groundless. 

The Supreme Court sustained the appellees’ standing 
to maintain this action. Stark v. Wickard, 321 U.S. 288. 
The intervenor, a New York cooperative not subject 
to the Order provisions here in issue, seeks to inject 
into the case a last minute attack upon their in¬ 
terest and good faith. The appellant voluntarily withdrew 
a motion to dismiss predicated on similar charges (Joint 
App. 466, 467). The intervenor is limited to the field of 
litigation between the parties. See Chandler & Price 


The intervenor refers to a “second finding” in 1944 by the 
Acting Director of Food Distribution (Intervenor-Appellant’s 
Brief, p. 23). The Appellant’s amended answer describes the same 
document as an “official conclusion”. It was a “Notice of Re¬ 
port” by the Acting Director of Food Distribution filed on March 
18, 1944* (9 F.R. 3057-3060). The conclusions therein were never 
incorporated into any official finding in the Order or any amend¬ 
ment thereto, and hence were never made and “set forth” as the 
Act requires [Sec. 8c(4) and (17)]. The report purports to be 
a statement by one official of considerations underlying action taken 
by a different official—three years earlier. It does reveal an un¬ 
fortunate confusion in the administrative mind as to the statutory 
basis for the contested provisions. 





37 


Co. v. Brandtzen & Klug, Inc., 296 U.S. 53, 58; Salem Engi¬ 
neering Co. v. National Supply Co., 75 F. Supp. 993; 
Reynolds Pen Co. v. Marshall Field do Co., 8 F.R.D. 314; 
Mueller v. Adler, 292 Fed. 138; Adler v. Seaman, 266 Fed. 
828, 842-843. The appellees properly objected in the District 
Court (Joint App. 467) to the intervenor’s belated attempt 
to question “the propriety of the main proceeding” or chal¬ 
lenge the status of the plaintiffs. 

In any event, the charge of champerty, maintenance and 
kindred aspersions by the intervenor are groundless. The 
findings of fact by the District Court are to the effect that 
each plaintiff is individually affected in a pecuniary way by 
the application of the cooperative deduction to his deliveries 
of milk as a “producer” under the Order (Joint App. 153, 
p. 2 supra). To a large cooperative like the intervenor, 
drawing the accumulated deductions of hundreds of pro¬ 
ducers from the fund, the financial interests of the appellees 
may seem “meagre” (Intervenor-Appellant’s Brief, p. 18); 
but the individual farmer, “practically all of whose time 
must be devoted to production” (Appellant’s Brief, p. 21), 
cannot be equally careless or callous about his personal 
financial loss. 

JThe District Court found that the plaintiffs “instituted 
this action” (Joint App. 153). Prior thereto they, and 
similarly situated farmers, had opposed the deduction at 
administration hearings (Joint App. 255, 332, 356). The 
producer referendum on the proposed deduction “gave 
producers an opportunity to vote only for or against the 
issuance of the entire Order as amended, and not on the 
newly proposed provisions for cooperative payments, sepa¬ 
rately and apart from the other provisions of the Order” 
(Findings of Fact, Joint App. 152). Hence the results of the 
referendum are no reflection of the widespread extent of the 
opposition to the challenged provisions among independent 
farmers in the milk shed (Joint App. 278, 332, 334). A group 
of such producers, meeting in the summer of 1941, and 


38 


including the appellees Stark and Denton, determined to 

take legal action (Joint App. 331-4). Before proceeding, 

they decided to ascertain whether producers in the area 

would support them. A large meeting was thereafter held 

in Colebrook, X. H., attended by producers from distant 

parts of the milk shed. Sentiment was strongly in favor of 

court action (Joint App. 334, 337). Hundreds of producers 

authorized deductions from their milk checks to defrav the 

•/ 

expenses of suit, creating a fund available for that purpose 
(Joint App. 308, 309, 360, 361). The plaintiffs Stark, 
Denton and Stratton employed counsel and authorized him 
to commence suit in their names because the joinder of 
some 1400 or 1500 producers would be cumbersone (Joint 
App. 339). Stark wrote to the appellee Stebbins, a Hood 
producer and representative farmer, who was glad to join in 
and contribute to the action (Joint App. 278, 279, 344). 
Stark went to the New York area, where he knew there was 
organized producer opposition to the amendment, and 
learned that the appellee Walsh was President of the inde¬ 
pendent producers association (Joint App. 340). Walsh 
subsequently agreed to join in the action to express his own 
and his organization’s views (Joint App. 260-1). No 
handler instigated or incited the appellees to commence this 
action (Joint App. 275, 278, 326-327, 349, 366). 

According to the appellant “it is impossible for the aver¬ 
age dairy farmer of small means to obtain the advantages 
obtainable by large organizations” (Appellant’s Brief, p. 
21-22). The intervenor paints the plight of the independent 
producer in even darker colors. “Unorganized producers 
are wholly unable to present to the Secretary any rational 
marketing programs. They have neither cohesion, knowl¬ 
edge of marketing problems, experience in marketing or 
legal and technical experts. On the other hand, the coop¬ 
eratives have all of these.” (Intervenor-Appellant’s Brief, 
p. 32). Manifestly when cooperatives are advocating price 
deductions from non-member producers, there is a diversity 


39 


of interest between the two groups. In such a situation, the 
independent producer without assistance is doomed to an 
uneven struggle against superior resources if the appel¬ 
lants’ statements as to his condition are accurate. The 
language of the Court, in Jahn v. Champagne Lumber Co., 
157 Fed. 407, 418, is thus particularly applicable: 

“It has never been held violative of law or public policy 
to give financial aid to a poor suitor who is prosecuting a 
meritorious cause of action. In the absence of any bargain 
to share the recovery, no just criticism can attach to one 
offering such friendly aid . . . The law does not tolerate 
the notion that a powerful defendant may force the aban¬ 
donment of a suit whenever he is able to exhaust the slender 
means of a weak antagonist.” 

Contributions to the expenses of this litigation by 
handlers do not close the portals of the courts to the 
appellees. As the District Court said: “ It would be equally 
unsound to bar a person from recourse to a judicial remedy 
merely because the expenses incurred by him in the litiga¬ 
tion are advanced, or borne by someone else. For example, 
were this the rule, many a matter involving civil rights 
could not have been brought before the courts in cases in 
which some organization is championing the rights of a 
poor person.” (Joint App. 145). A handler may come to 
the assistance of a producer who has been shipping milk to 
it for over a quarter of a century (Joint App. 145), and 
who is seeking to protect his milk check from an illegal 
invasion by powerful and resourceful associations with 
their “legal and technical experts.” Such aid is not 
champerty or maintenance. The Hood Company was also 
a large producer of milk and subject to the contested deduc¬ 
tion (Joint App. 457-460). A person may contribute with 
entire propriety to the expense of litigation which affects 
his own legal position (6 Williston, Contracts (Rev. Ed. 
1937) § 1714). 




40 


The history of the case shows that appellees were vindi¬ 
cating: the rights of hundreds of similarly situated non¬ 
member producers, as well as their own individual rights. 
Hence the action could properly be characterized as a class 
suit. In any event, they had the right to bring this action 
in their individual capacities. The District Court properly 
entertained it as such, particularly in the light of the state¬ 
ment by the United States Supreme Court (321 U.S. 288, 
305): “We deem it clear that on the allegations of the 
complaint these producers have such a personal claim as 
justifies judicial consideration. ” 


CONCLUSION. 

For the foregoing reasons the Judgment of the District 
Court should be affirmed. 

Respectfully submitted, 

Edward B. Hanify 

Harry Polikoff 

Attorneys for Appellees , 
Delbert O. Stark et al. 

Edgar J. Goodrich 

Lipman Redman 

Ring Building 
Washington, D. C. 

Of Counsel. 
















United States Court of Appeals for the 
District of Columbia. 

October Term, 1949. 

Nos. 10,365 and 10,366. 

CHARLES F. BRANNAN, Secretary of Agriculture, 

Appellant, 

AND 

DAIRYMEN’S LEAGUE COOPERATIVE 
ASSOCIATION, INC., Intervenor Appellant, 

v. 

DELBERT 0. STARK et al., Appellees. 

On Appeal from an Order from the United States Dis¬ 
trict Court for the District of Columbia. 


BRIEF OF NEW ENGLAND MILK PRODUCERS’ 
ASSOCIATION, UNITED FARMERS OF NEW 
ENGLAND, INC., ET AL., AMICI CURIAE. 


REUBEN HALL, 

WALDO NOYES, 

Boston, Massachusetts, 

GEORGE H. THOMPSON, 

Bellows Falls, Vermont, 

Attorneys for Amici Curiae. 


Marion R. Garstang, 

Harry Scharnikow, 

1731 Eye Street, 
Washington, D.C., 

Of Counsel. 



. W */ . i ^ / W V I If ' 


ADDISON C. GETCHELL A SON, XAF J^JNTBB*. .30ST0K. J 








Subject Index. 


Page 

Foreword 1 

Statement of interest 2 

Statutes and orders involved 2 

Statement of the case 3 

Statement of points 3 

Argument 4 

Point I 4 

Point II 7 

Conclusion 15 

Table of Authorities Cited. 

Cases. 

Ada County v. Oregon Short Line R. Co., 97 F. (2d) 

666 5 

American Power & Light Co. v. Securities & Ex¬ 
change Commission, 329 U.S. 90 5 

Builders Club of Chicago v. United States, 58 F. 

(2d) 503 5 

Dobson v. Co mmi ssioner of Internal Revenue, 320 
U.S. 489 6 

Gemsco, Inc. v. Walling, 324 U.S. 244 5,6 

National Labor Relations Board v. Hearst Publica¬ 
tions, Inc., 322 U.S. Ill 6 

Porter v. Murray, 156 F. (2d) 781 15 

Robin Goodfellow, The, 20 F. (2d) 924 - 5 

Sioux Tribe of Indians v. United States, 316 U.S. 317 15 

United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 
U.S. 533 5,7 



11 


AUTHORITIES CITED 


Page 

United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 26 
F. Sup. 534 7 

Yakus v. United States, 321 U.S. 414 5 

Statutes. 

Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (Act 
of June 3, 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 246, 7 U.S.C. 601 
et seq.) 2 

Section 8c (3) 6 

Section 8c (4) 6 

Section 8c (5) (6) (7) 3,4 

Section 8c (5) (B) 6 

Section 8c (5) (C) 8 

Section 8c (7) (D) 3,4,6,7,15 

Boston Milk Marketing Order as amended (6 F.R. 

3762, 5481, 7 C.F.R. 1941 Sup. 904.0 et seq.; and 
12 F.R. 4921, 7 C.F.R. 1947 Sup. 904.0 et seq.) 2, 5 

Senate Report No. 1719, Seventy-sixth Cong., Third 
Sess. 13 

S. 3426, U.S. Senate, Seventy-sixth Cong., Third 
Sess. 8,9,11,12,13,15 

Order No. 27, issued Aug. 1938 7 



UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS 
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA. 


October Term, 1949. 


Nos. 10,365 and 10,366. 

CHARLES F. BRANNAN, Secretary of Agriculture, 

Appellant, 

and 

DAIRYMEN’S LEAGUE COOPERATIVE 

ASSOCIATION, INC., Intervenor Appellant, 

v. 

DELBERT 0. STARK et al., Appellees. 


On Appeal from an Order from the United States Dis¬ 
trict Court for the District of Columbia. 


BRIEF OF NEW ENGLAND MILK PRODUCERS’ 
ASSOCIATION, UNITED FARMERS OF NEW ENG¬ 
LAND, INC., ET AL., AMICI CURIAE. 


Foreword. 

New England Milk Producers’ Association; United 
Fanners of New England, Inc.; Bellows Falls Cooperative 
Creamery, Inc.; Bethel Cooperative Creamery; Connecti¬ 
cut Valley Dairy, Inc.; Grand Isle Cooperative Creamery; 




2 


Granite City Cooperative Creamery, Inc.; Milton Coopera¬ 
tive Dairy Cooperation; Mt. Mansfield Cooperative Cream¬ 
ery & Grain Association, Inc.; Richmond Cooperative 
Creamery; Shelburne Cooperative Creamery Company; 
Tunbridge Cooperative Creamery, Inc.; by their counsel 
respectfully submit herewith their Brief as Amici Curiae 
in the within cause, all parties having previously assented. 


Statement of Interest. 

The several cooperative corporations whose names are 
set forth in the next preceding paragraph are all coopera¬ 
tive associations of producers of milk organized and ex¬ 
isting under the laws of Massachusetts, Vermont and New 
Hampshire, engaged in the marketing of milk in the 
Greater Boston marketing area. They are cooperative 
associations of producers determined by the Secretary of 
Agriculture as qualified to receive certain payments under 
the provisions of Section 904.9 of Order No. 4 as amended 
regulating the handling of milk in the Greater Boston, 
Massachusetts, milk marketing area, which section of said 
Order was challenged as illegal by the appellees in their 
complaint filed in the Court below. 

Statutes and Orders Involved. 

The relevant parts of the Agricultural Marketing Agree¬ 
ment Act of 1937 (Act of June 3, 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 246, 
7 U.S.C. 601 et seq.) and the Boston Milk Marketing Order 
as amended (6 F.R. 3762, 5481, 7 C.F.R. 1941 Sup. 904.0 
et seq.; and 12 F.R. 4921, 7 C.F.R. 1947 Sup. 904.0 et seq.). 

The foregoing sections of the Agricultural Marketing 
Agreement Act of 1937 and of the Marketing Order are set 
forth in the appendix to the Brief as filed on behalf of 
Charles F. Brannan, Secretary of Agriculture, and in the 



3 


Brief filed on behalf of the Dairymen’s League Coopera¬ 
tive Association, Inc., Intervenor Appellant, pages 2 to 
5, inclusive. 


Statement of the Case. 

The statement of the case contained in the Appellant’s 
Brief is hereby adopted. 

The interpretation of the relevant sections of the Agri¬ 
cultural Marketing Agreement Act and of the Order issued 
by the Secretary of Agriculture as discussed and presented 
in the Briefs of the Appellant and Intervenor Appellant 
are hereby adopted. 

The interpretation claimed here is not contrary thereto, 
but in support of and supplemental to it. 


Statement of Points. 

I. 

The determination of the Secretary that the deductions, 
that is, the sums paid to cooperatives for market-wide ser¬ 
vices, were incidental to and not inconsistent with the 
terms and conditions specified in Section 608c (5) (6) (7) 
of the Act and were necessary to effectuate the other pro¬ 
visions of his Order was an administrative determination 
by the Secretary of his powers and a construction of the 
Act entitled to great weight. 

H. 

Section 608c (7) (D) of the Agricultural Marketing 
Agreement Act of 1937 as amended (7 U.S.C. 601 et seq.) 
confers on the Secretary of Agriculture authority and 
power to include within the terms of the Boston Milk Mar¬ 
keting Order as amended provisions for payments to co¬ 
operative associations of producers for market-wide ser- 


4 


vices. The District Court erred, therefore, in adjudging 
that these provisions of the amended Order are not au¬ 
thorized by the Act and the District Court was in error in 
enjoining the Secretary from making the payments to the 
cooperative associations of the producers as provided in 
the amended Order. 


Argument. 

Point I. 

The determination of the Secretary that the deductions, 
that is, the sums paid to cooperatives for market-wide ser¬ 
vices, were incidental to and not inconsistent with the 
terms and conditions specified in Section 608c (5) (6) (7) 
of the Act and were necessary to effectuate the other pro¬ 
visions of his Order was an administrative determination 
by the Secretary of his powers and a construction of the 
Act entitled to great weight. 

The Act is the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act 
of 1937 (7 U.S.C. 601 et seq.). Section 8c (5) provides 
that, with respect to milk and its products, orders issued 
thereunder shall contain one or more of the terms and con¬ 
ditions therein specified and (except as provided in sub¬ 
section (7)) no others. 

Section 8c (7) provides for the inclusion in all orders of 
one or more of the terms and conditions therein specified. 
Paragraph (D) is as follows: 

“(D) Incidental to, and not inconsistent with, the 
terms and conditions specified in subsections (5)-(7) 
and necessary to effectuate the other provisions of 
such order.” 

Considerable flexibility is provided by Section 8c (7) 
(D) as to the terms and conditions which may be included 



5 


in milk orders. 1 Suck terms and conditions must, how¬ 
ever, be auxiliary to those definitely specified and must be 
within the limitations of being incidental to, not incon¬ 
sistent with, other provisions and necessary to effectuate 
the other. 

“Incidental” has been defined as something additional, 
accessory or collateral to something else as primary. 2 

The word “necessary” does not mean and should not be 
construed to mean “indispensable, inevitable, essential or 
vital,” nor merely “convenient or profitable,” but some¬ 
where in between. 3 

The incidental and necessary provision of the Act must 
be viewed as part of the whole texture of the Act and of 
the policy which the Act is designed to effectuate. It has 
been held that, where Congress has entrusted to an ad¬ 
ministrative agency the responsibility of selecting the 
means of achieving the statutory policy, the relation of 
remedy to policy is a matter for administrative compe¬ 
tence and its judgment is entitled to the greatest weight. 4 

An examination of the challenged provisions demon¬ 
strates that these provisions are not inconsistent with the 
other provisions of the Order which relate to classified 
price and equalization and the mechanics of effectuating 
them. 

The performance of the services by the cooperatives 
outlined in Section 904.10 of the Order results in substan¬ 
tial benefits to producers as a whole and causes consider¬ 
able expense to the cooperatives. Since such expense 

'United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U.S. 533, 
575. 

2 Builders Club of Chicago v. United States, 58 F. (2d) 503, 505. 
The Robin Goodfellow, 20 F. (2d) 924. 

3 Ada County v. Oregon Short Line R. Co., 97 F. (2d) 666, 671. 

4 American Power & Light Co. v. Securities & Exchange Com¬ 
mission, 329 U.S. 90. Gemsco, Inc. v. Walling, 324 U.S. 244. 
Ydkus v. United States, 321 U.S. 414. 



6 


must be reflected in the return to its producers, it would be 
difficult, if not impossible, for a cooperative to continue to 
perform these services without compensation. Since these 
services are necessary to secure the efficient operation of 
the Order, it follows that the payments to cooperatives are 
not only necessary “equitably to apportion” (Section 8c 
(5) (B) of the Act) the total value of milk among all pro¬ 
ducers, but are also necessary to effectuate the other pro¬ 
visions of such order. 

It was the duty of the Secretary under Sections 8c (3), 
8c (4) and 8c (7) (D) to insert in the Order provisions to 
effectuate the policy of the Act. In order to fulfill this 
obligation, the Secretary must have power to use every 
reasonable means in his judgment necessary to effectuate 
the desired end. The determination of the Secretary based 
on substantial evidence at the hearings before him as to 
what provisions of an order are incidental and necessary 
to effectuate the other provisions of the Order and the broad 
policies of the Act must be conclusive unless clearly for¬ 
bidden by the terms of the Act itself or clearly abuse of dis¬ 
cretion. 5 

Questions of statutory interpretation, especially arising 
in the first instance in judicial proceedings, are for the 
courts to resolve, giving appropriate weight to the judg¬ 
ment of those whose special duty is to administer the ques¬ 
tioned statute; but where the question is one of specific 
application of a broad statutory term in a proceeding in 
which the agency administering the statute must determine 
it initially, the reviewing court’s function is limited, and 
the administrative interpretation is to be accepted if it has 
warrant in the record and a reasonable basis in law. 6 

5 Gemsco, Inc., v. Walling, 324 U.S. 244. 

6 National Labor Relations Board v. Hearst Publications, Inc., 
322 U.S. 111. Dobson v. Commissioner of Internal Revenue, 320 
U.S. 489. 




7 


Point IL 

Section 608c (7) (D) of the Agricultural Marketing 
Agreement Act of 1937 as amended (7 U.S.C. 601 et seq.) 
confers on the Secretary of Agriculture authority and 
power to include within the terms of the Boston Milk Mar¬ 
keting Order as amended provisions for payments to co¬ 
operative associations of producers for market-wide ser¬ 
vices. The District Court erred, therefore, in adjudging 
that these provisions of the amended Order are not au¬ 
thorized by the Act and the District Court was in error in 
enjoining the Secretary from making the payments to the 
cooperative associations of the producers as provided in 
the amended Order. 

Within a few months after the enactment of the Agri¬ 
cultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 the Secretary 
of Agriculture issued an Order regulating the marketing 
of milk in the New York Market. 7 Included in this Order 
was a provision for payments to cooperative associations 
similar in their nature to the payments challenged by this 
litigation. 

Prior to the Order being made effective, wide publicity 
was given to the proposed Order and to this particular 
provision. 

The Order was challenged in the District Court and the 
District Court ruled with respect to the provision relat¬ 
ing to the cooperative payments that the Secretary was 
without statutory authority to include such a provision 
within the New York Order. 8 

Upon review the Supreme Court held that handlers had 
no standing to challenge the propriety of this particular 
provision of the New York Order.® Following the decision 

7 Order No. 27, issued August, 1938. 

8 United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 26 F. Sup. 534, 
553. 

®United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U.S. 533. 




8 


of the Supreme Court the Secretary reissued the Order, 
retaining within it the provision for payments to coopera¬ 
tives. 

In 1940 Senator Gillette introduced in the Senate a bill 
to amend the Agricultural Adjustment Act as it had been 
amended by the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 
1937. This Bill was known as S. 3426. Section 4 of that 
Bill provided that Section 8c (5) (C) be amended by add¬ 
ing the following paragraph: 

“ ‘Providing further (i) reasonable compensation 
(to be paid out of any pool or fund) established under 
this paragraph (C) of subsection (5), as determined 
by the Secretary, to bona fide cooperative marketing 
associations, all of whose operations are under the full 
control of milk producers, for services rendered to 
producers of milk or its products covered by the order 
by performing such marketing functions specified 
therein as the Secretary determines will tend to effec¬ 
tuate the declared policy of this Act, including but not 
by way of limitation, handling of surplus milk, or mak¬ 
ing available to the market a sufficient supply of milk 
at all times: Provided, however, That no such compen¬ 
sation shall be paid to any cooperative association 
which does not comply with the applicable provisions 
of the order: * # V’ 

The Bill was referred by the Senate Committee on Agri¬ 
culture to the Department of Agriculture for comment. 

In the letter from the Secretary of Agriculture to the 
Committee on Agriculture dated March 30, 1940, the Sec¬ 
retary made the following comment: 

“Section 4 amends Section 8c (5) (C) by providing 
specific authority for the making of certain payments 
out of any pool or funds, where the market-wide pool 



9 


plan of settlement is used, to cooperatives and to oper¬ 
ators of plants for certain services performed. Such, 
payments are frequently necessary to insure adequate 
supplies of milk at all times within the market and to 
make proper arrangements for the handling of the 
surplus. Owing to the different services performed by 
the various factors in the milk market, the making of 
such payments will permit more equitable operation 
of milk orders. ’ ’ 10 

Accompanying the Secretary’s letter was a comparison 
of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 be¬ 
fore and after amendment as proposed by S. 3426, with 
explanatory remarks. 

With respect to Section 4, above quoted, the comment 
made was as follows: 

1 ‘The third proposed amendment to Section 8c (5) 
of the Act, being Section 4 of S 3426, adds new lan¬ 
guage to the present law which makes clear and defi¬ 
nite the authority to provide in a marketing order 
regulating milk and its products for the payment of 
cooperative and market service differentials. 

“The proposed amendment, while embraced in a 
single paragraph, expresses two independent author¬ 
izations—one designated (I) and the other designated 
(II). 

“That part designated (I) refers to payments to 
cooperatives for rendering services to the market. 
Such payments are authorized in the present law by 
virtue both of Section 8c (5) (B) and Section 8c (7), 
• • * and Section 8c (7) providing 1 In the case of 
agricultural commodities and the products thereof 

10 Record of Hearings before the Subcommittee of the Committee 
on Agriculture and Forestry, United States Senate, Seventy-sixth 
Congress, Third Session, on S. 3426. 



10 


specified in subsection (2) orders shall contain one or 
more of the following terms and conditions: * * *. 

“ ‘(D) Incidental to, and not inconsistent with, the 
terms and conditions in subsections (5), (6) and (7) 
and necessary to effectuate the other provisions of 
such order’. 

“The reason assigned by the Secretary in support 
of the proposed amendment is stated as follows: 

“Reason.—In order to make definite and certain 
the Secretary’s authority in this regard and to settle 
the question that insufficient standards are spelled out 
in the act to guide the Secretary, it is regarded as es¬ 
sential that the law be amended in the respects con¬ 
templated by section 4 of S. 3426. 

“The market services for which these payments 
may be made to a qualifying cooperative are clearly 
set forth in the brief of the United States Government 
in the case of United States v. Rock Royal Co-opera¬ 
tive, Inc., et al. (307 U.S. 533, 59 S. Ct. 993, pp. 158 
et seq.), which may be paraphrased as follows: 

“(1) Service performed in the supplying class I 
milk to the marketing area in times of short supply; 

“ (2) Service performed in the utilization of milk in 
times of long supply in such manner as to insure the 
greatest possible return to producers; 

“(3) Service performed by the maintenance 
throughout the year of facilities for handling the sea¬ 
sonable surplus even though these facilities can be 
employed only during the flush season; 

“ (4) Service performed for the market by the em¬ 
ployment of measures during flush periods of produc¬ 
tion to secure the utilization in fluid form of milk near 
to the market, and the utilization in manufactured 
form of milk produced at the edge of the milkshed, 
thus reducing transportation charges which must be 
shared by all producers; 



11 


“(5) Miscellaneous services performed for the ben¬ 
efit of the entire market with respect to weights, tests, 
market outlets, etc. 

“The amendment proposed in section 4 of S. 3426, 
namely, part (I) thereof, will make it clear and cer¬ 
tain that the Secretary of Agriculture in his discre- « 
tion has full power to fix differentials in favor of co¬ 
operative associations which are rendering these or 
similar services and which services tend to effectuate 
the public policy of the Marketing Agreement Act. By 
the amendment the Secretary will have authority to 
fit such payments appropriately to the value of the 
service rendered. 

“It is to be noted that as a prerequisite to receiving 
any such payment, the cooperative must be bona fide 
and under the exclusive control of its member-pro¬ 
ducers. Furthermore, it must be in full compliance 
with all provisions of the marketing order which gov¬ 
ern it.” 11 

At the hearing held before a sub-committee on the Com¬ 
mittee on Agriculture of the Senate, Dr. E. W. Gaumnitz, 
Director, Division of Marketing and Marketing Agree¬ 
ments, Agricultural Adjustment Administration, Depart¬ 
ment of Agriculture, made this statement with respect to 
Section 4 of S. 3426: 

“Section 4 * * *, amending Section 8c (5) (C), rec¬ 
ognizes and now provides specifically that the power 
to fix minimum prices to handlers and the manner of 
making payments to producers can include in the total 
segregation from the total value of milk, as fixed by 
an order, a sum to provide a reasonable compensation 

11 Record of Hearings before the Subcommittee of the Commit¬ 
tee on Agriculture and Forestry, United States Senate, Seventy- 
sixth Congress, Third Session, on S. 3426, p. 26. 



12 


to bona fide producer-owned and producer-controlled 
associations for services which they may render to the 
entire market, and from which all producers derive 
benefits.” 12 


In response to a question from Senator Schwellenbach, 
Mr. Gaumnitz stated as follows: 

“Again it is primarily a matter of attempting to 
avoid controversy and litigation. Provisions similar 
to that carried in this section have been included in 
certain of the milk orders, specifically that for New 
York, which was before the Supreme Court, and on 
which the Supreme Court ruled favorably. However, 
it is one of those provisions that are controversial in 
character, and it was thought that the inclusion of a 
specific authority might eliminate, in whole or in part, 
additional litigation with respect to the enforcement 
of marketing agreements and orders.” 13 

In answer to a further question from Senator Schwellen¬ 
bach to whether the amount allowed as reasonable was con¬ 
troversial or the principle was questioned, Mr. Gaumnitz 
stated: 

“The first question is as to principle, and it would 
appear that the court has pretty well passed on the 
principle, although it is still a controversial point. 
The question of reasonableness has not come up di¬ 
rectly. 7 7 13 

12 Record of Hearings before the Subcommittee of the Committee 
on Agriculture and Forestry, United States Senate, Seventy-sixth 
Congress, Third Session, on S. 3426, pp. 52-53. 

13 Record of Hearings before the Subcommittee of the Committee 
on Agriculture and Forestry, United States Senate, Seventy-sixth 
Congress, Third Session, on S. 3426, pp. 52-53. 


13 


No opposition appeared before the Senate Committee on 
Agriculture with respect to those provisions of S. 3426 in¬ 
cluding Section 4 thereof having to do with milk orders. 
The bill was favorably reported by the Committee on 
Agriculture to the Senate. 14 

In the report discussing Section 4 the Committee said: 

“Section 4 of the amending bill amends section 8c 
(5) (C) of the act by providing specifically for the 
segregation, from the total value of milk as fixed by 
the order, of sums to provide reasonable compensation 
for two distinct kinds of marketing services as indi¬ 
cated in the provisions designated as (I) and (II). 
This authority is considered as being involved in the 
power to fix minimum prices to handlers and the man¬ 
ner of making payments to producers already con¬ 
tained in the act. Hence, the purpose of section 4 is 
to establish more explicit standards by which the Sec¬ 
retary shall be guided in providing for such compen¬ 
sation. Both types of services are definitely associ¬ 
ated with the proper functioning of an order program 
and the effectuation of the policy of the act. 

“The services for which compensation is author¬ 
ized by the provision designated by (I) are of the type 
regarded as essential in carrying out the method of 
payment to producers authorized by paragraphs (B) 
(II) and (C) of subsection (5) of section 8c under the 
method of pricing milk to handlers provided in para¬ 
graph (A) of the same sub-section. Authorization of 
such compensation to be paid out of any pool or fund 
established under paragraph (C) of subsection (5) in¬ 
volves the fundamental principle that such services 
be those which are identifiable as benefiting all pro¬ 
ducers with a reasonable degree of equality as distin- 

14 Senate Report No. 1719, Seventy-sixth Congress, Third Ses¬ 
sion, pp. 7 and 8. 




14 


guished from services, the benefits of which are lim¬ 
ited primarily to members of a particular cooperative 
association. Illustrations of these types of market¬ 
ing services are suggested in the amendment itself, 
but the Secretary is authorized to specify others which 
may conform to these general principles when neces¬ 
sary to achieve the same marketing results under cir¬ 
cumstances peculiar to different markets. Because 
of the nature of such services, compensation with re¬ 
spect thereto is limited to bona fide cooperative mar¬ 
keting associations, all of whose operations are under 
the full control of milk producers. 

“The services for which compensation is author¬ 
ized by the provision designated by (II) are in addi¬ 
tion to and in no way a duplication of the services for 
which compensation is authorized under (I). The 
payments authorized by (II) are similar to location 
differentials now authorized, having to do with the 
movement and handling of milk, and are available to 
any plant operator, irrespective of whether or not 
such operator is also a cooperative association. This 
type of allowance is designed to cover costs involved 
in the movement of milk from or to processing plants 
when marketing conditions are such as to necessitate 
such movement in order to maximize returns to all 
producers. 

“Eligibility of an association or operator to receive 
payments authorized by (I) and (II) from a pool or 
fund as established by an order is further conditioned 
upon compliance with the applicable provisions of the 
order. These two provisions supplement each other 
and together provide a way whereby all producers who 
enjoy the benefits of such marketing services also 
carry a reasonable and proportionate share of the 
burden involved.” 



15 

S. 3426 was passed by the Senate, bnt no action was 
taken by the Honse. 

The foregoing legislative history establishes clearly that 
in construing Section 8c (7) (D) the Court must rule that 
the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 author¬ 
ized and empowered the Secretary to include within the 
terms of the Boston Federal Milk Order the provision for 
the cooperative deductions here being contested. 

Sioux Tribe of Indians v. United States, 316 
U.S. 317, 329; 

Porter v. Murray, (C.A. 1) 156 F. (2d) 781, 785. 


Conclusion. 

The judgment of the lower court sustaining the amended 
bill of complaint should be reversed and the amended com¬ 
plaint should be dismissed. 

Respectfully submitted, 

REUBEN HALL, 

WALDO NOYES, 

Boston, Massachusetts, 

GEORGE H. THOMPSON, 
Bellows Falls, Vermont, 

Attorneys for Amici Curiae. 


Mart otst R. Garstang, 

Harry Scharxikow, 

1731 Eye Street, 
Washington, D.C., 

Of Counsel. 




REPLY BRIEF FOR THE SECRETARY OF AGRICUL¬ 
TURE, APPELLANT 


®mteb States Court of 

FOB THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT 

October Term, 1^49 


Nos. 10,365 «hwHK£906 , ‘' 


Charles F. Brannan, Secretary of Agriculture, 

APPELLANT 

». I 

Delbert 0. Stark, et al., appellees 
Dairymen’s League Co-operative Association, Inc., 

APPELLANT 


v. • I 

Delbert 0. Stark, et al., appellees 


ON APPEAL FROM A JUDGMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 
DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA 


Gi fppzzls. 




- * y f s 


- ^ ' 


J. STEPHEN DOYLE. JR.. 

NEIL BROOKS. 

Special Assistants to the Attorney General . 
LEWIS A. SIGLER. 

Assistant Associate Solicitor. 
MARY CONNOR MYERS. 

Attorney, 

U. S. Department of Agriculture. 


| 

i 










INDEX 


Page 


Restatement of the Issues. 1 

Summary of Argument . 2 

Argument . 6 


I. The uniform prices under $ Sc(5) of the Act relate to 
payments for milk. The payments to co-operatives 
are for services performed, and not for milk sold or 
delivered by producers. The co-operative payments, for 
services performed under the order, are permissible sub¬ 
tractions in the computation of the uniform blended price, 
and are not variations or adjustments to the uniform 

prices under the Act. 6 

II. The payments to co-operatives for market-wide services 
are not antithetical or repugnant to the terms and condi¬ 
tions in section 8c (5) of the Act. There is, therefore, 
no basis for the appellees’ contentions that the payments 
to cooperatives are “inconsistent” under section 
8c(7) (D) of the Act with the terms or conditions in 
section 8c (5) of the statute. 20 

III. Assuming, arguendo, that the payments to cooperatives 

are “adjustments” to the uniform prices in addition to 
the adjustments expressly, set forth in $Sc(5)(A) and 
(B), such additional adjustments for co-operative pay¬ 
ments are permissible under $ 8c(7) (D) of the Act. 22 

IV. The Boston milk order is explicit in requiring the per¬ 

formance of market-wide services by the co-operatives 
that receive the payments, and the appellees’ criticism 
of the order in this respect fails to refer to other signifi¬ 
cant provisions in the order. 26 

V. The scope of judicial review is limited, and the validity of 

the provisions for payments to cooperatives depends 
on whether substantial evidence in the hearing record 
supports the Secretary’s findings. The hearing record 
on which the present order provisions are based is not 
before this Court and, therefore, since the provisions for 
cooperative payments are not prohibited by the Act, 


there can be no holding that the provisions are invalid.. 29 

Conclusion . 31 

Appendix: 

Relevant sections of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement 

Act of 1937 . 32 

Relevant findings with respect to the Boston milk marketing 

order . 36 

Relevant sections o£ the Boston milk marketing order. 37 


(I) 

















n 


^ CITATIONS 

Cases: Page 

Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Anderson (C.A. S), 157 F. 2d 87, 

cert, denied, 329 U. S. 78S.4, 6, 7,17 

Belknap v. Shock, 125 W. Va. 385, 24 S. E. 2d 457. 20 

Bodkin v. State, 132 Neb. 535, 272 N. W. 547. 20 

Bond v. Phelps, 200 Okla. 70, 191 P. 2d 938. 20 

Brotrn v. Duchesne, 19 How. 1S3. 22 

Cardillo v. Liberty Mutual Insurance Co., 330 U. S. 469. 31 

City of Mobile v. Collins, 24 Ala. App. 41, 130 So. 369 . 20 

Colgate Company v. United States, 320 U. S. 422. 31 

Commonwealth v. Staunton Mutual Telephone Co., 134 Va. 

291, 114 S. E. 600 . 20 

Costanzo v. Tillinghast, 287 U. S. 341. 19, 22, 25 

Dairymen's League Co-operative Association, Inc. v. Brannan 

(C.A. 2), 173 F. 2d 57. 10 

Ex parte Public Bank, 278 U. S. 101 . 25 

Ginsberg <£' Sons v. Popkin, 285 U. S. 204. 25 

Grandview Dairy v. Jones (C.A. 2), 157 F. 2d 5, cert, denied, 

329 U. S. 787. 3,6,13,14 

Green Valley Creamery v. United States (C.A. 1), 10S F. 2d 

342 . 3, 4, 6,10,15,16 

Helvering v. New York Trust Company, 292 U. S. 455 . 22 

Helvering v. Stockholms Enskilda Bank, 293 U. S. S4 . 22 

In re Robertson (D.C. N.D. Tex.), 20 F. Supp. 270 . 20 

Ketchum v. United States (C.A. 8), 270 Fed. 416 . 20 

Lehigh Valley Coal Company v. Yensavage, 218 Fed. 547. 18 

Lichter v. United States, 334 U. S. 742. 18 

Louisville Water Co. v. Clark, 143 U. S. 1. 20 

McCaughn v. Hershey Chocolate Company, 2S3 U. S. 4SS. 19 

Murphy Oil Co. v. Burnett, 287 U. S. 299. 19 


National Labor Relations Board v. Hearst Publications, Inc., 


322 U. S. Ill. 31 

National Lead Company v. United States, 252 U. S. 140. 19 

Nebbia v. New York, 291 U. S. 502. 18 

Philadelphia Company v. Securities and Exchange Commission, 

— App. D. C. —, 177 F. 2d 720. 31 

Queensboro Farm Products, Inc. v. Wickard (C.A. 2), 137 F. 

2d 969 . 4, 6,10,19, 30 

Roland Electrical Co. v. Walling, 326 U. S. 657 . 31 

Secretary of Agriculture v. Central Roig Refining Company, 

33S U. S. —, 70 S. Ct. 403, 94 L. Ed. 297 . 25 

Shields v. Utah Idaho Central R. Co., 305 U. S. 177. 6, 31 

Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288 . 7, 8,18 

State v. Dairy Distributors, 217 Wis. 167, 258 N. W. 3S6. 26 

State ex rel. Kipker v. City of Lima, — Ohio App. —, 32 N.E. 

2d 48S . 20 


Thompson v. Consolidated Gas Utilities Corporation, 300 U. S. 

55 . 30 

Unemployment Compensation Commission v. Oregon, 329 U. S. 

143, 153-154 .. 31 












































rn 


Cases—Continued 


Page 


United States v. American Trucking Association, 310 U. S. 

534 . 31 

United States v. Jackson, 280 U.S. 183. 31 

United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 

533 . 4,5, 6, 8,11,15,18,24,25,30 

Waddington Milk Co. v. Wickard (C.A. 2), 140 F. 2d 97.4, 6,17 

Wallace v. Hudson-Duncan <k Company (C.A. 9), 98 F. 2d 


985 . 30 

White v. United States, 305 U. S. 281. 22, 25 


Statutes and Orders: 


Act of July 3, 1948, c. 827, 62 Stat. 1258, 7 U.S.C. Supp. II, 

672 . 19 

Section 302(e) . 19 

Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, c. 296, 50 Stat. 

246, 7 U.S.C. 601 et seq.2,16,17, 30 

Section 8c(5) . 2,4,5, 6,10,11,16,17,18, 20, 21,22, 23 

Section 8c(5) (A) .2, 3,4,5, 6, 7,11,12,17,21,22,23, 24,25 

Section 8c(5) (B) .2, 3,4,5, 6,7, 9,12,17,19, 21,22, 23 

Section 8c(5) (B) (i) . 15 

Section 8c(5) (C) . 8 

Section 8c(7) .5,23,25 

Section 8c(7)(B) . 23 

Section 8c (7) (D) . 2,4,5,10,16,19, 20,21,22,24,25 

Section 8c (18) . 10 

Section 10(b) . 24 

Boston Milk Order . 2,5, 8, 9,11,15,21,26, 28,29 


Section 904.8 . 8 

Section 904.8(b) . 2 

Section 904.8(b)(4) . 21 

Section 904.8(b)(7) . 8,11 

Section 904.9 . 11 

Section 904.9(d) . 8,21 

Section 904.9(e) . 8,21 

Section 904.10 . 27 

Section 904.10(a) . 27 

Section 904.10(b) . 27 

Louisville Milk Order . 14 

Lowell-Lawrence Milk Order. 15 

Section 934.9(b)(2) . 15 

New York Milk Order.3,12,14 

Section 927.7(b)(2) . 13 

Section 927.7(f) . 13 

11 F.R. 640 . 29 


Miscellaneous: 

Docket No. AO-14-A12, in office of Hearing Clerk, U. S. Dept. 

of Agriculture, Washington, D. C. 30 

Gaumnitz and Reed, Some Problems Involved in Establishing 
Milk Prices (U. S. Department of Agriculture, 1937). 16 










































Miscellaneous—Continued 


17 


Page 


Hearings before Subcommittee No. 4 of the Committee on the 
Judiciary on H.R. 4236, H.R. 6198, and H.R. 6324, 76th 

Cong., 1st Sess. (1939) at 161. 10 

Lininger, The Dairy Industry and the Agricultural Adjustment 

Act (The Brookings Institution, Pamphlet Series No. 13)... 16 

Sen. Rep. No. 1241, 74th Cong., 1st Sess. (1935). 16 

Sen. Rep. No. 565, 75th Cong., 1st Sess. (1937). 19 

Stitts and Gaumnitz, Relative Prices to Producers Under 
Selected Types of Milk Pools (Farm Credit Administration, 

Bulletin No. 5) . 16 

The New York Market Administrator’s Bulletin. 14 










©niteb States (Court of Appeals 

FOB THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT 

October Term, 1949 


Nos. 10,365 and 10,366 

Charles F. Brannan, Secretary of Agriculture, 

APPELLANT 


V. 

Delbert 0. Stark, A. F. Stratton, A. R. Denton, G. 
Stebbins, and F. Walsh, appellees 


Dairymen’s League Co-operative Association, Inc., 

appellant 

v. 

Delbert 0. Stark, A. F. Stratton, A. R. Denton, G. 
Stebbins, and F. Walsh, appellees 


ON APPEAL FROM A JUDGMENT OF THE UNITED STATES 
DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA 


REPLY BRIEF FOR THE SECRETARY OF AGRICULTURE, 

APPELLANT 


RESTATEMENT OF THE ISSUES 

A restatement of the issues is necessary, in view of the 
appellees’ brief, in order to impose precision upon the ad¬ 
verse arguments. The appellees stake the case on a reading 


(1) 



2 


of the statute and the provisions in the Boston milk order; 
no question is presented by the appellees as to whether 
substantial evidence supports the findings of the Secretary 
that the payments to co-operatives, for the services per¬ 
formed, are necessary to effectuate the classification, pric¬ 
ing, and pooling provisions of the order. The appellees 
submit (appellees’ brief, pp. 5-8) as their decisive conten¬ 
tions that (1) the payments to co-operatives are “adjust¬ 
ments” in the minimum prices fixed under §8c(5) of the Act, 
and that such adjustments for payments to co-operatives 
are not authorized by $ 8c(5) and are, therefore, violative 
of the Act inasmuch as § 8c(5) sets forth the “only” adjust¬ 
ments that may be made; and (2) the activities of a co-oper¬ 
ative for which payments are made, as set forth in the order, 
are “primarily, and almost exclusively, to its own mem¬ 
bers” but even if the co-operatives do perform market-wide 
services of value to all producers, payments for such mar¬ 
ket-wide services are “inconsistent” with § 8c(5) and, 
therefore, cannot be regarded as incidentally necessary un¬ 
der § 8c(7) (D) of the Act. The relevant sections of the Act 
and the order are in the Appendix, infra , pp. 32-42. 

SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT 

The requirements of the Act with respect to uniform 
prices relate to payments for milk. The payments to co¬ 
operatives, however, are for services performed, and not 
for milk sold or delivered. Also, if the uniform prices 
are subject only to the adjustments enumerated in § 8c(5) 
(A) and (B) of the statute, as contended by the appellees, 
it is clear nonetheless that the adjustments result in some 
producers receiving more than other producers for the 
same volume of milk. The statute permits variations, i.e., 
adjustments, in the payment of the uniform prices, but 
that is not involved in this case. The payments to the 
co-operatives are for market-wide services, and there is no 
variation or adjustment in the uniform class price or in the 
uniform blended price for milk. 

The co-operative payments are subtracted, under the 
terms of § 904.8(b) of the Boston order, prior to the result 
of the computation of the uniform blended price; under 




3 


the plain terms of the order the uniform blended price is 
paid without any variation or adjustment, in that price, for 
co-operative payments. The only adjustments to the uni¬ 
form blended price in the order are those expressly enumer¬ 
ated in § 8c(5) (B) of the Act. 

The Act “does not specify the detailed method by which 
a blended or uniform price is to be computed.” Green 
Valley Creamery v. United States (C. A. 1), 108 F. 2d 342, 
345. If milk orders are to be effective or operative, some 
necessary subtractions—in addition to the subtractions for 
co-operative payments—have to be made in the process of 
arriving at the uniform blended price. An irrefutable ex¬ 
ample is in § 904.8(b) (7) of the Boston order whereby sub¬ 
traction is made for establishing and maintaining a cash 
reserve. Each of the 26 milk orders for market-wide pools, 
effective under the Act, provides for a cash reserve by 
means of subtractions in the process of computing or arriv¬ 
ing at the uniform blended price. In the absence of a cash 
reserve, the failure of any handler to make full payment to 
the Market Administrator would result in the insolvency 
of the equalization fund; and the insolvency of the equali¬ 
zation fund would inevitably destroy uniformity in prices 
under the Act. The subtraction of the money for a cash 
reserve—just as the subtraction for co-operative payments 
for services rendered—does not, in any way, introduce a 
variation or additional adjustment to the uniform prices 
under § 8c(5) (A) and (B) of the statute. 

Another example of a necessary subtraction in the process 
of computing the uniform blended price is in the original 
New York order (7 CFR, 1938 Supp., 927.1 et seq.) for the 
New York metropolitan marketing area effective September 
1, 1938. Under that order from September 1, 1938, to No¬ 
vember 16, 1942, the total of approximately 13 million dol¬ 
lars was paid to handlers—not merely to co-operatives— 
for performing market-wide services in diverting milk from 
fluid milk plants to manufacturing plants for processing 
into certain products. These diversion payments, as de¬ 
scribed in Grandview Dairy v. Jones (C. A. 2), 157 F. 2d 
5, 6, certiorari denied, 329 U. S. 787, involving claims for 




4 


diversion payments for market-wide services, were sub¬ 
tracted—in the same manner as co-operative payments are 
now subtracted—in the computation of the uniform blended 
price. 

The milk orders reveal other instances in which it has 
been necessary to make various subtractions, e.g., season¬ 
ality payments to encourage dairy farmers to produce more 
milk in periods of short supply and less milk in periods of 
surplus milk; and the subtractions do not introduce any 
additional adjustment or variation in the payment of the 
uniform blended price. Making a subtraction in computing 
the uniform blended price is governed by the standard of 
what is “incidental . . . and necessary,” on the basis 
of evidence at the public hearing, to make effective the 
classification, pricing, and pooling provisions in the order. 
Subtracting milk from the pool or subtracting payments 
for marketwide services is in accord with the rationale of 
Green Valley Creamery v. United States (C. A. 1), 108 
F. 2d 342, 345, and United States v. Rock Royal Co-opera¬ 
tive, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 565-566, 575-576. 

The provisions in § 8c(5) (A) and (B) of the Act are not 
requirements of “literalness or consumptive ultimacv” but 
should be given such meaning as will not defeat the regula¬ 
tory purpose of the Act. Bailey Farm Dairy Company v. 
Anderson (C. A. 8), 157 F. 2d 87, 94, certiorari denied, 
329 IT. S. 788. There can be no doubt that Congress gave 
the Secretary broad discretion in the administration of 
the Act. Queensboro Farm Products, Inc. v. Wickard (C. 
A. 2), 137 F. 2d 969, 977; and Waddington Milk Company v. 
Wickard (C. A. 2), 140 F. 2d 97, 100. 

The payments to co-operatives for market-wide services 
are not antithetical or repugnant to the terms and condi¬ 
tions in § 8c(5) of the Act, and there is therefore no basis 
for the appellees’ contention that the payments to co¬ 
operatives are “inconsistent” under §Sc(7)(D) of the Act 
with the terms or conditions in § 8c(5) of the statute. A 
provision is “inconsistent” only if it is contradictory and 
antagonistic in the sense that the one nullifies the other 
so that the two cannot co-exist. There is no such repug- 




5 


nance in this case. It is uncontroverted that the making of 
co-operative payments does not prevent the making of the 
adjustments expressly authorized by §8c(5)(A) and (B) 
of the statute. There is no antithesis between the co-opera¬ 
tive payments for services rendered and the statutory ref¬ 
erence to a uniform class price or a uniform blended price 
for milk sold or delivered. 

Assuming, arguendo, that the payments to co-operatives 
are adjustments to the uniform prices in addition to the 
adjustments set forth in § Sc(5) (A) and (B), the payments 
to co-operatives are permissible under §8c(7)(D) of the 
Act. The prefatory passages in §8c(5) and §8c(7) of 
the Act expressly state that a milk order may contain terms 
or conditions based on either of those sections. It is set¬ 
tled that a milk order may contain auxiliary provisions 
under §8c(7). United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, 
Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 575-576. Each term or condition in 
§8c(5)(A) and (B) is qualified by the introductory ref¬ 
erence to additional provisions that may be included under 
§8c(7)(D) of the statute. Any reference in §8e(5)(A) 
and (B) to the adjustments therein set forth as being 
the “only” adjustments means that those are the only ad¬ 
justments except as provided in §8c(7)(D) of the Act. 
This construction of the Act gives meaning and significance 
to all of its provisions. 

The Boston order is explicit in requiring the performance 
of market-wide services by the co-operatives that receive 
the payments. The appellees’ criticism of the order in 
this respect fails to refer to other significant provisions in 
§ 904.10(b) of the order. Moreover, the bill of complaint 
(Joint App. 1-7) does not assert a failure to be explicit 
in the order; the complaint asserts the absence of any statu¬ 
tory authority for co-operative payments. If this is an 
instance in which the order should be more explicit in set¬ 
ting forth the market-wide services to be performed by the 
co-operatives, any such defect is independent of, and has no 
relevance to, the statutory authority to provide in an order 
for necessary payments to co-operatives for market-wide 
services. If the appellees are now to question whether these 







6 


services, as set forth in the order, are necessary to effectuate 
the declared policy of the Act, a review of the hearing record 
is necessary. The appellees failed to include in the record 
in this case the hearing record on which the provisions for 
co-operative payments are now in effect. That forecloses, 
in the absence of a prohibition in the Act, any question 
as to the validity of these provisions. Shields v. Utah 
Idaho Central R . Co., 305 U. S. 177. The findings of 
the Secretary, on the basis of the evidence at a public 
hearing, carry a presumption of the existence of a state 
of facts justifying the action. United States v. Rock Royal 
Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 567-568; and Queensboro 
Farm Products v. Wickard (C. A. 2), 137 F. 2d 969, 977-9S1. 

ARGUMENT 

7. The Uniform Prices Under § 8c(5) of the Act 
Relat&Vto Payments for Milk. The Payments to Co-op¬ 
eratives are for Services Performed, and not for Milk 
Sold or Delivered by Producers. The Co-operative 
Payments, for Services Performed under the Order, 
are Permissible Subtractions in the Computation of 
the Uniform Blended Price, and are not Variations or 
Adjustments to the Uniform Prices under the Act. 

The appellees’ argument (appellees’ brief, pp. 5-8) is 
that the payments to cooperatives “creates a new price 
adjustment,’’ and is therefore violative of the provisions in 
§ Sc(5)(A) and (B) of the Act, which provide for uniform 
prices to be paid for milk “subject only” to the adjustments 
set forth in §8c(5)(A) and (B) of the statute. The ap¬ 
pellees’ argument is refuted by the plain provisions of the 
Act and the order, and the appellees’ argument, in seeking 
a constringent construction of <§>8c(5)(A) and (B) of the 
Act, conflicts with the interpretation and application of 
those provisions of the statute in United States v. Rock 
Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533; Green Valley Cream¬ 
ery v. United States (C. A. 1), 108 F. 2d 342; Queensboro 
Farm Products, Inc., v. Wickard (C. A. 2), 137 F. 2d 969; 
Waldington Milk Company v. Wickard (C. A. 2), 140 F. 
2d 97; Grandview Dairy v. Jones (C. A. 2), 157 F. 2d 5, 
certiorari denied, 329 U. S. 787; and Bailey Farm Dairy 





7 


Company v. Anderson (C. A. 8), 157 F. 2d 87, certiorari 
denied, 329 U. S. 788. 

It is provided in § 8c(5) (A) of the Act 1 that the minimum 
class prices for milk sold or delivered by producers shall 
be uniform, subject to the variations or adjustments therein 
set forth; and under §8c(5)(B) of the Act the blended 
price for milk sold or delivered by producers shall be uni¬ 
form subject to the variations or adjustments set forth 
in §8c(5)(B). These requirements of uniformity, subject 
to the enumerated variations or adjustments, permit all 
producers to share equitably in the disposition of the milk 
that is priced under the order. The co-operative payments 
are not made for milk sold or delivered, but for services 
performed. The co-operative payments cannot, therefore, 
be said to impinge on the “uniformity” requirements rela¬ 
tive to the class prices or the blended price to be paid for 
milk. An analysis of the pricing provisions in the order 
reveals that a payment to co-operatives, for services per¬ 
formed, does not constitute a variation or adjustment in the 
uniformity of the class prices or in the uniformity of the 
blended price to be paid for milk sold or delivered by pro¬ 
ducers. 

The minimum class prices under the order apply to the 
two “use” classifications prescribed in accordance with 
§8c(5)(A) of the Act. There is no requirement in the 
statute that a uniform blended price must be provided 
for in addition to the minimum class prices, but the evi¬ 
dence as to market conditions in the Boston area is, as 
explained in Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288, 295, that 
“serious inequities as among producers might arise if the 
prices received depended on the use the handler might 
happen to make of his milk,” and therefore under §8c(5) 
(B) of the Act, “provision is made for the payment to 
producers of a uniform [blended] price for the milk de¬ 
livered irrespective of the use to which the milk is put by 
the individual handler.” The payment of the uniform 
blended price is accomplished by an equalization or pro- 


1 This section of the Act and related sections are set forth in the 
Appendix to this brief, infra , pp. 32-36. 




8 


ducer-settlement fund under § 8c(5) (C) of the statute. 
Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288, 295; and United States v. 
Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 571. The han¬ 
dler whose milk has a use value in excess of the minimum 
blended price pays the excess into the equalization or pro¬ 
ducer-settlement fund, and the handler who puts his milk to 
a lower value use than the minimum blended price receives 
the difference from the Market Administrator out of the 
equalization or producer-settlement fund. 

The uniform blended price is computed in accordance 
with the terms in <§904.8 of the order 2 , and in short the 
computation is made in this manner: The Market Admin¬ 
istrator computes the value of milk for each handler by 
multiplying the quantities used by the handler in each 
class by the class price and by adding the two results. 
Then the values for all handlers are combined into one 
total. That total is increased or decreased by several nec¬ 
essary additions and subtractions, including a subtraction 
for payments to co-operatives for market-wide services. 
The resulting total is then divided by the total quantity 
of milk, and the result is described in <§ 904.S(b) (7) of the 
order as the basic or uniform blended price. 

The producers receive 3 the uniform blended price, sub¬ 
ject only to the adjustments enumerated in the order, e. g., 
the butterfat differential under <§ 904.9(d) and the location 
differential under § 904.9(e) of the order. But to the uni- 


2 This section of the order and related sections are set forth in 
the Appendix to this brief, infra, pp. 36-42. 

3 In some instances a handler, by reason of having a utilization 
of milk higher than the average for the milk during that month, 
will be obligated, under the class prices, to pay more for his milk 
than the uniform blended price. In such case, the handler pays 
the uniform blended price to his producers and pays the balance 
to the Market Administrator for deposit in the equalization or 
producer-settlement fund, and this money is then used to pay 
handlers who, by reason of having a greater utilization of milk 
in the lower class, are obligated to pay, under the class prices for 
their milk, less than the uniform blended price. The Market Ad¬ 
ministrator pays to each such handler a sum which, when added 
to the total value of the handler’s milk at the class prices, will en¬ 
able him to pay his producers at the uniform blended price. In 
this method equalization is effectuated among handlers. 



9 


form blended price there is no exception, variation, or 
additional adjustment for payments to co-operatives for 
services performed. 

The statute states in §8c(5)(B) that a milk order may 
provide “for the payment to all producers and associations 
of producers delivering milk to all handlers of uniform 
prices for all milk so delivered . . . subject . . . only 
to adjustments for (a) volume, market, and production dif¬ 
ferentials customarily applied by handlers subject to such 
order, (b) the grade or quality of the milk delivered, (c) 
the locations at which delivery of such milk is made, and 
(d) a further adjustment, equitably to apportion the total 
value of the milk purchased by any handler, or by all 
handlers, among producers and associations of producers, 
on the basis of their marketings of milk during a repre¬ 
sentative period of time.” Under the terms of the Boston 
order, the uniform blended price is paid for all milk 
sold or delivered, and the payment of the uniform blended 
price is not subject to an exception, variation, or additional 
adjustment for payments to co-operatives for services 
performed. The very terms of the order refute the ap¬ 
pellees’ contention that a payment to co-operatives for 
services rendered is an additional adjustment to the uni¬ 
form blended price. 4 

It is also contended by the appellees (appellees’ brief, 
p. 26) that even though there is no “adjustment” for co¬ 
operative payments, nonetheless the method for computing 

* The payments to co-opcratives are to reimburse, in part at least, 
the co-operatives for expenses incurred in the performance of market¬ 
wide sendees of substantial value to the market as a whole. The 
appellees do not question that substantial evidence supports the 
Secretary’s findings as to the necessity for these payments and 
sendees. It may be reasonably concluded that the uniform blended 
price is higher than it would have been if these market-wide sen- 
ices had not been performed. The appellees’ argument merely comes 
to the point that if these market-wide services were performed by 
the co-operatives wdthout being paid to do so, then the blended 
price would be higher. It cannot be expected that the co-operatives 
can perform the market-wide senices without some reimbursement 
for the additional expenses incurred in the performance of the 
senices. 




10 


the uniform blended price does not, under the statute, per¬ 
mit any latitude for a subtraction—such as is made for 
co-operative payments—from the fund prior to the computa¬ 
tion of the uniform blended price. The appellees’ argu¬ 
ment is in conflict with the holding in Green Valley Cream¬ 
ery v. United States (C. A. 1), 108 F. 2d 342, 345, that the 
Act “does not specify the detailed method by which a 
blended or uniform price is to be computed.” The ap¬ 
pellees’ assertion that any latitude or allowable discretion 
with respect to the computation of the blended price leaves 
“the fund entirely unprotected” fails to recognize that 
the standard of necessity governs the Secretary in pre¬ 
scribing the terms or conditions under the “incidental 
. . . and necessary” authorization in §8c(7)(D) of the 
Act. It can hardly be said that the fund is left “entirely 
unprotected” if the Secretary’s action, in order to achieve 
the economic goal set forth in §Sc(18) of the Act, is gov¬ 
erned by a finding, on the basis of the evidence adduced at 
a public hearing, that each regulatory provision in the 
order is “necessary” to effectuate the declared policy of 
the Act. 5 It is settled that in addition to the terms and con¬ 
ditions set forth in §8c(5) of the Act, a milk order may 
contain additional provisions under § 8c(7) (D) “auxiliary 

•'* The Secretary, in seeking the economic goal set forth in the 
statute, is not dealing with concrete factors but factors that “are 
extremely intangible, such as different types of economic situations, 
broad objectives that must be definitized to meet concrete situations, 
different methods of control, technical methods and procedures and 
a variety of relationships.” Hearings before Subcommittee No. 4 
of the Committee on the Judiciary on H.R. 4236, H.R. 6198, and 
H.R. 6324, 76th Cong., 1st Sess. (1939) at 161. Wide discretion 
is vested in the Secretary in devising methods or regulatory plans 
to achieve the economic goal of the statute. Queensboro Farm 
Products v. Wickard (C.A. 2), 137 F. 2d 969, 980. The “mon¬ 
strous difficulty” of classifying, pricing, and pooling milk and the 
“multifarious ramifications of such a subject as milk regulation” 
are such that with respect to some of its aspects “we [the Judiciary] 
should have to endow them [the administrators] with almost super¬ 
human powers, if they were not, like ourselves, at the outset stunned 
and confounded by the fantastic proliferation which emerges.” 
Dairymen's League Co-operative Association , Inc. v. Brannan 
(C.A. 2), 173 F. 2d 57, 65, the opinion of the Court being by Judge 
Learned Hand. 





11 


to those definitely specified” in §8c(5) of the statute. 
United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 
533, 575-576. 

There is nothing in the Act—and the appellees have 
pointed to nothing in the Act—that prohibits the Secre¬ 
tary from making a necessary subtraction in the computa¬ 
tion of the uniform blended price. The necessity for such 
latitude, if milk orders are to be operative, is evident 
from inescapable examples. In § 904.8(b) (7) of the Boston 
order, it is provided that in computing the uniform blended 
price the Market Administrator shall subtract not less 
than four cents nor more than five cents per hundredweight 
“for the purpose of retaining a cash balance in connec¬ 
tion with the payments set forth in <§> 904.9. ’ ’ That sub¬ 
traction—not referred to in the statute—is the last step 
in the process of computing the uniform blended price. 
If there were no provision in the order for this subtraction 
for the purpose of accumulating and maintaining the cash 
reserve, the total amount of money required to be paid by 
all the handlers in the market to all of their producers 
would exactly equal the total of all of the milk at the 
established class prices; and the payments required to be 
made into the equalization or producer-settlement fund 
would exactly equal the amounts required to be paid out 
of the fund. Hence the failure of any handler to make full 
payment to the Market Administrator would result in the 
insolvency of the equalization or producer-settlement fund. 
In that situation the Market Administrator could not make 
full payment out of the fund, and the failure of a handler 
to receive full payment due from the fund would be regarded 
as relieving him from the obligation to pay producers at 
the uniform blended price. If, on the contrary, the handler 
should be required to pay the uniform blended price with¬ 
out having received full payment from the equalization or 
producer-settlement fund, the handler would pay for his 
milk at a rate above the uniform class prices set forth in the 
order. This would destroy uniformity in prices under 
§8c(5)(A) of the Act. In addition, if the handler main¬ 
tained uniformity with respect to the class prices under 






12 


§ Sc(5) (A) of the Act, it could be done only by paying his 
producers less than the uniform blended price and thereby 
destroying uniformity under §8c(5)(B) of the Act. 

It cannot be expected, as a practical matter, that every 
handler in a large metropolitan marketing area will always 
make full payment to the equalization or producer-settle¬ 
ment fund within the time specified in the order. Errors 
in reports by handlers, controversies with respect to the 
classification of milk, and other circumstances may result in 
delays in making full payments to the equalization or pro¬ 
ducer-settlement fund. Each of the 26 milk orders for 
market-wide pools contains a provision, therefore, for 
the establishment of a cash reserve. The subtraction of the 
money for the cash reserve, in computing the uniform 
blended price, does not affect at all the degree of uniformity 
between producers as to the prices that they receive for 
their milk. The deduction for the cash reserve is made 
prior to the result that is known as the uniform blended 
price, and the uniform blended price is paid to producers 
without any variation or adjustment for the cash reserve. 

The appellees’ argument that there is no authority in the 
statute for the making of any subtraction in the process of 
computing the uniform blended price would, in some major 
instances, prevent the Secretary from effectuating the eco¬ 
nomic objectives of the statute. An example which involved 
payments to handlers—not merely payments to co-opera¬ 
tives—for performing market-wide services is found in the 
original order (7 CFR, 1938 Supp., 927.1 et seq.) for the 
New York metropolitan marketing area, effective September 
1, 1938. The necessity for the diversion of milk from fluid 
milk plants to manufacturing plants was so compelling that 
on the basis of the evidence at the bearing, the Secretary 
provided, in the New York order, for payments to handlers 
for diverting milk “received from producers at a plant 
. . . , equipped only for the receiving and shipping of 
milk to the marketing area, which was . . . moved to a 
plant where it was utilized” in the production of certain 
milk products and from which “no Class I milk was shipped 
to the marketing area during such month.” These diver- 



13 


sion payments to handlers were subtracted, under § 927.7 
(b) (2) of the New York order, in the computation of the 
uniform blended price, and therefore the uniform blended 
price was paid to producers without any variation or ad¬ 
justment in that price for the diversion payments to hand¬ 
lers for market-wide services. This is described in Grand¬ 
view Dairy v. Jones (C. A. 2), 157 F. 2d 5, 6, certiorari de¬ 
nied, 329 U. S. 787, involving claims for diversion payments 
for market-wide services under the order: 

. . Each handler is required to report to the 
Milk Administrator the quantity of milk used in each 
class. The total of the use value of all handlers ( less 
the total allowance made to all such handlers as have 
diverted excess fluid milk into market products under 
the terms of Sec. 927.7(f) ) is divided by the total 
quantity of milk received from all producers. The re¬ 
sult is announced by the Milk Administrator as the 
uniform price to be paid by all handlers to producers. 
The variance among handlers in the percentage of milk 
used in a given class will normally mean that the total 
use value for a particular handler may be greater or 
less than the total payments at the uniform price re¬ 
quired to be made by him to his producer. Any handler 
for whom there is a plus difference is required to pay 
the difference into the Producers-Settlement-Fund, 
while any handler for whom there is a minus difference 
is entitled to withdraw the difference from the fund. 
Payments into the fund constitute the only source of 
withdrawal from the fund. This price mechanism is 
applicable to each monthly delivery of milk. Handlers 
are entitled to an allowance paid out of the Producers- 
Settlement-Fund known as marketing service or diver¬ 
sion payments for diverting excess fluid milk into milk 
products. The uniform prices paid to producers are 
reduced as against the handlers to the extent of the 
aggregate amount of such allowance. Diversion allow¬ 
ances may be had where the plant of the handler is 
equipped only for the receiving of milk for disposition 
in the marketing area. The plant of diversion must be 
a second plant located outside the marketing area.” 
(Emphasis supplied.) 

The need for diversion payments to handlers under the 
New York order became less pronounced during the early 







14 


part of the war, and eventually the order was amended 
(7 F.R. 9109) so as to eliminate the provisions for pay¬ 
ments to handlers for market-wide services in diverting 
milk from fluid milk plants to manufacturing plants. But 
from September 1, 1938, to November 16, 1942, the per¬ 
formance of these services by handlers was a major factor 6 
in making effective the classification, pricing, and pooling 
provisions in the New York order. The appellees’ argu¬ 
ment that the Secretary has no discretion or authority to 
make any subtraction in the computation of the uniform 
blended price would prohibit the making of diversion or 
market service payments to handlers as set forth in the 
sections of the New r York order involved in Grandview 
Dairy , Inc . v. Jones (C. A. 2), 157 F. 2d 5, certiorari denied, 
329 U. S. 787. 

A similar subtraction is made in the Louisville milk order 
(7 CFR, 946.7(b)(3)), for seasonality payments, and the 
subtraction—as with co-operative payments—is made in 
the computation of the uniform blended price, and the uni¬ 
form blended price is paid to producers without any varia¬ 
tion or adjustment to that price for the seasonality pay¬ 
ments. Other orders also contain a similar provision for 
these payments designed to encourage dairy farmers to 
produce more milk in the periods of short supply and less 
milk in the periods of surplus supply. The appellees’ argu¬ 
ment that the Secretary has no discretion or leeway in 
the computation of the uniform blended price -would render 
the Secretary impotent to deal with the pressing needs of 


6 The claims by various handlers for payments involved in the 
narrow issue in Grandview Dairy, Inc. v. Jones (C.A. 2), 157 F. 
2d 5, totaled in excess of one million dollars. See, the Record, p. 
51, in No. 619 in the Supreme Court of the United States for the 
October Term. 1946, in Grandview Dairy, Inc. v. Jones, on petition 
for certiorari to the United States Circuit Court of Appeals for 
the Second Circuit, certiorari denied, 329 U. S. 787. The total 
of the diversion payments to handlers under the New York order 
was approximately thirteen million dollars. The New' York 
Market Administrator’s Bulletin, Vol. 3, No. 7 (January 1943), 
pp. 8-9. 







15 


these milk markets in which the orders provide for these 
payments. 7 

The validity of the subtractions for necessary payments 
in the computation of the uniform blended price is in accord 
with the rationale of Green Valley Creamery v. United 
States (C. A. 1), 108 F. 2d 342, 345, permitting the exclusion 
of milk, under certain circumstances, from the pool—even 
though the milk thus excluded is priced under the order— 
in the computation of the uniform blended price; it being 
the opinion of the Court that the “method adopted . . . 
seems reasonably adapted to promoting the successful oper¬ 
ation of the equalization pool,” and leeway in this respect 
is granted by the Act inasmuch as it “does not specify the 
detailed method by which a blended or uniform price is to 
be computed.” Moreover, the exclusion of milk from the 
pool, in applying the uniform blended price, was upheld in 
United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 
533, 565-566. 

Subtracting milk or subtracting payments from the pool, 
in computing the uniform blended price, is governed by the 
standard of what is “incidental . . . and necessary” 
to make effective the classification, pricing, and pooling 
provisions in the order. If the requisite necessity exists, 
the Secretary is authorized by the statute to include, under 

7 There are other instances in which it has been necessary for 
the Secretary to provide for subtractions in the computation of 
the price for milk. See e.g., the order (7 CFR, 934.1 et seq.) for 
the Lowcll-Lawrence marketing area in which the composite price, 
for the individual handler pool under §8c(5) (B) (i) of the Act, is 
arrived at after a subtraction, in § 934.9(b) (2) of the order, of 
“any amounts which the handler is required to pay on such milk 
pursuant to those provisions of the order of the Secretary regulating 
the handling of milk in the Greater Boston, Massachusetts, market¬ 
ing area (i) which requires a handler under that order who operates 
an unregulated plant from which outside milk is disposed of to 
consumers in the Greater Boston, Massachusetts, marketing area, 
without intermediate movement to another plant, to make pay¬ 
ments to producers as defined in that order, and (ii) which require 
payments for administrative expense under that order.” In the 
absence of such subtractions for milk under the Lowell-Lawrence 
order that is also regulated in some respects by the Boston order, 
uniformity of prices for milk could not be properly achieved. 





16 


§ 8c(7)(D) of the Act, provisions “auxiliary to those defi¬ 
nitely specified” in § 8c(5) of the Act. United States v. 
Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 575-576. If 
the uniform prices are “subject only” to the adjustments 
set forth in detail in § 8c(5) of the Act, as contended for by 
the appellees, the remaining area for the use of auxiliary 
provisions in milk orders is in relation to the computation 
of the uniform blended price as to which the Act does not set 
forth any details. Green Valley Creamery v. United States 
(C. A. 1), 108 F. 2d 342, 345. 

The making of necessary subtractions, for payments for 
market-wide services, in the computation of the uniform 
blended price is consonant with the methods of pooling by 
co-operatives at the time of the enactment of this legislation 
and as to which Congress included authority in the statute 
for such methods of pooling to be included in milk orders. 
The principles of class prices, on the basis of “use classi¬ 
fication,” and the pooling of milk were developed 8 by the 
co-operatives and later included by Congress in the Act. 9 
The pooling practices of co-operatives related to a mingling 
or averaging of prices w’hereby the sales and expenses w’ere 
apportioned among the producers in the group. 10 

s Gaumnitz and Reed. Some Problems Involved in Establishing 
Milk Prices (U.S. Department of Agriculture, 1937), pp. 30-41; 
and Liningcr. The Dairy Industry and the Agricultural Adjust¬ 
ment Act (The Brookings Institution, Pamphlet Series No. 13), pp. 
13-19. Pooling by a co-operative tends to prevent discrimina¬ 
tion in the allocation of surplus milk within that group of producers, 
and thereby permits all members of that co-operative to share 
equally in the co-operative’s share of the fluid milk market, i.e., 
the higher priced milk. Under the Boston order, however, a handler 
is not required to buy or accept delivery of milk, surplus or other¬ 
wise; and by declining to buy or accept delivery of milk a handler 
may, in the absence of some other outlet for the milk, place on a 
particular producer or co-operative an unequitable share and dis¬ 
proportionately heavy burden of surplus milk. 

9 "These terms [of classifying, pricing, and pooling milk under 
§8c(5) of the Act] follow the methods employed by co-operative 
associations of producers prior to the enactment” of this legislation. 
Sen. Rep. No. 1241, 74th Cong., 1st Sess. (1935) p. 9. 

10 Stitts and Gaumnitz, Relative Prices to Producers Under 
Selected Types of Milk Pools (Farm Credit Administration, Bulle¬ 
tin No. 25, June 1938), pp. 1-4. 



17 


The argument of the appellees that the provisions in 
§ 8c(5) of the statute are rigid symbols or a code of abso¬ 
lutes is in conflict with the holding in Bailey Farm Dairy 
Company v. Anderson (C. A. 8), 157 F. 2d 87, 94, certiorari 
denied, 329 U. S. 788, that §8c(5)(A) and (B) of the Act 
is not to be read with “a literal significance which would 
defeat the regulatory purpose of the Act,” and provisions 
in that section are not to be regarded as requirements of 
‘ 4 literalness or consumptive ultimacy, ’ ’ but should be ‘ ‘ given 
practical regulatory significance in relation to handlers’ 
processes and the effect of their mode of doing business 
upon the market problem.” 

The appellees’ argument for a narrow and constringent 
construction with respect to § 8c(5)(A) and (B) is also in¬ 
consistent with the rationale in Waddington Milk Company 
v. Wickard (C. A. 2), 140 F. 2d 97,100, in which it was held 
that § 8c(5) (A) and (B) of the Act should be construed 
with all of the other sections in the statute so as to give 
significance to the “purpose for which classification is 
made,” and the provision as to uniformity “should not con¬ 
trol or vitiate the classification directed in the first sentence; 
the prices within the proper and authorized classifications 
should be uniform, rather than that uniformity of prices 
to handlers should be had, whatever has been the classifica¬ 
tion.” In the Waddington Milk Company case the Court 
held (140 F. 2d at 101) that in dealing with § 8c(5) of the 
statute: 

“. . . it is necessary to have in mind the problems 
confronting the Congress in passing the Act and the 
Secretary in establishing the order. The need of regu¬ 
lation, as has so often been pointed out, was very great, 
but so were the difficulties. No simple and arbitrary 
classification of the milk to determine the form and 
manner of payment to be made by the distributors 
seemed adequate in view of the many different uses 
to which fluid milk could be devoted and its prime neces¬ 
sity as an article of diet, the alternate periods of glut 
and scarcity, so striking a feature of milk production, 
the requirements of quick marketing or else of expen¬ 
sive storage, and the many other problems of the busi- 



18 


ness . . . Given the conditions and the purpose, there 
appears to be nothing unreasonable in selecting as the 
controlling point for determination for the form in 
which milk is to be classified . . . the time when it 
leaves the initial receiving plant of the distributor.” 

The provisions in a remedial statute are not to be con¬ 
strued “as theorems of Euclid, but with some imagination 
of the purposes which lie behind them.” Lehigh Valley 
Coal Company v. Y ensavage, 218 Fed. 547, 553. The terms 
of § Sc(5) of the Act are not to be interpreted so as to 
render nugatory the legislative purpose for equalization 
of the burdens of surplus milk. United States v. Rock 
Royal Co-operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 579-580. The terms 
of a milk order “are largely matters of administrative dis¬ 
cretion,” and “the technical details are left to the Secretary 
and his aides.” Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S. 288, 310. What 
was said in Licliter v. United States, 334 U. S. 742, 785, is 
also an explanation of the situation here: 

“It is not necessary that Congress supply adminis¬ 
trative officials with a specific formula for their guid¬ 
ance in a field where flexibility and the adaptation of 
the congressional policy to infinitely variable condi¬ 
tions constitute the essence of the program. • • • 

Standards prescribed by Congress are to be read in 
the light of the conditions to which they are to be ap¬ 
plied. ‘They derive much meaningful content from 
the purpose of the Act, its factual background and the 
statutory context in which they appear.’ ” 

The Congress recognized, in vesting in the Secretary 
broad discretion with respect to the provisions to be in¬ 
cluded in a milk order, that a rigid and inflexible method 
of pricing milk cannot be applied in dealing with the di¬ 
vergent and mutable situations in the various milk market¬ 
ing areas. “The intricate problems of the milk industry, 
as described in the above cited opinion [Nebbia v. New 
York , 291 U. S. 502], explain the use of the several pooling 
and pricing plans authorized for inclusion in milk orders,” 
and their “effectiveness depends upon their adaptability 










19 


to conditions affecting each marketing area and upon their 
adjustment from time to time to meet changing conditions.” 
Sen. Rep. No. 565, 75th Congress, 1st Sess. (1937), p. 3. 
There can be no doubt 11 that Congress gave to the Secre¬ 
tary broad discretion in the administration of the Act. 
Queensboro Farm Products , Inc. v. Wichard (C. A. 2), 137 
F. 2d 969, 977. 

The payments to co-operatives are not, under the plain 
provisions of the order, adjustments to the uniform blended 
price; the uniform blended price is paid for milk subject 
only to the adjustments expressly authorized by § 8c(5) (B) 
of the Act. 12 The co-operative payments are subtracted 
prior to the result of the computation known as the uni¬ 
form blended price; and under $ 8c(7)(D) of the Act the 
Secretary is authorized to make subtractions from or addi¬ 
tions to the pool in the process of computing the uniform 
blended price whenever the requisite necessity exists on 
the basis of evidence at a public hearing. Without that 
authority, milk orders cannot be operative or effective. 


11 This is given even greater emphasis by the failure of Congress 
to amend the Act after it was apprised in 1940 of the administra¬ 
tive construction whereby co-operative payments are made under 
the milk orders; and this creates a presumption in favor of the 
administrative interpretation to which great weight should be given. 
Costanzo v. Tillinghast, 287 U. S. 341, 345; McCaughn v. Hershey 
Chocolate Company, 283 U. S. 488, 492-493; and Murphy Oil 
Company v. Burnet, 287 U. S. 299, 302-303. In addition, the Act 
of July 3, 1948, c. 827, 62 Stat. 1258, providing in Title III, §302 
(e) of the enactment (7 U.S.C. Supp. II, 672), that all milk orders 
in effect “shall continue in effect without the necessity for any 
amendatory action” indicates an implied legislative recognition 
and approval of the administrative construction of the statute. 
National Lead Company v. United States, 252 U. S. 140, 146-147. 

12 This result is not dependent on that part of § 8c (5) (B) which 
authorizes an additional adjustment “equitably to apportion the 
total value of the milk.” However, as explained in our main brief, 
p. 27, that provision of §8c(5)(B) constitutes an adequate basis. 
There is nothing in the statute to indicate that it is limited, in 
this respect, to a “base rating plan,” as contended for by the ap¬ 
pellees (appellees’ brief, pp. 11-13). 



20 


II. The Payments to Co-operatives for Market-Wide 
Services Are Not Antithetical or Repugnant to the 
Terms and Conditions in Section 8c(5) of the Act. 
There is, Therefore, No Basis for the Appellees' Con¬ 
tention That the Payments to Co-operatives are “In¬ 
consistent” Under Section 8c(7) (D) of the Act With 
The Terms or Conditions in Section 8c(5) of the 
Statute. 

The appellees assert (appellees’ brief, p. 24) that even if 
the payments to co-operatives for market-wide services 
are incidental and necessary under § 8c(7)(D) of the Act 
in order to effectuate the classification, pricing, and pooling 
provisions of the order, nonetheless the payments to co¬ 
operatives are prohibited by the provision in § 8c(7)(D) 
against including a provision that is “inconsistent with” 
§ 8c(5). This argument by the appellees conflicts with the 
established rule that an “inconsistent” limitation in a stat¬ 
ute merely applies to provisions that are contradictory and 
antagonistic in the sense that one nullifies the other so that 
the two cannot co-exist. Bodkin v. State, 132 Neb. 535, 272 
X.W. 547; Bond v. Phelps, 200 Okla. 70, 191 P. 2d 938; 
Belknap v. Shock, 125 W. Va. 385, 24 S.E. 2d 457; Common¬ 
wealth v. Staunton Mutual Telephone Co., 134 Va. 291, 114 

S.E. 600, 603; State ex rel. Kipker v. City of Lima, - 

Ohio App.-, 32 N.E. 2d 488, 496; and City of Mobile v. 

Collins, 24 Ala. App. 41, 130 So. 369, 371. The mere lack 
of uniformity is not necessarily proof of inconsistence. 
Ketchum v. United States (C. A. 8), 270 Fed. 416, 417-420, 
and In re Robertson (D.C. N.D. Tex.), 20 F. Supp. 270, 273. 
For an inconsistent limitation in a statute to be applicable, 
there must be a “positive repugnance.” Louisville Water 
Company v. Clark, 143 XT. S. 1,11. If an auxiliary provision 
is necessary in a milk order, it may be included under 
§ Sc(7) (D) of the Act unless it is so antithetical to the pro¬ 
visions of § 8c(5) that the two cannot be operative at the 
same time. 

It is uncontroverted that there is no such antithesis in the 
Boston milk order as to prevent the Market Administrator 





21 


from giving full effect to all of the provisions in the order, 
including the adjustments expressly authorized by §8c(5) 

(A) and (B) of the statute. It is uncontroverted that the pay¬ 
ments to co-operatives for market-wide services do not de¬ 
stroy or interfere in any way with making the other adjust¬ 
ments in the order expressly enumerated in § 8c(5) (A) and 

(B) of the Act. No repugnance has been disclosed; none ex¬ 
ists. There is no antithesis or repugnance between the co¬ 
operative payments and the statutory reference in § 8c(5) 
(A) and (B) to the ‘‘uniform” class price or a “uniform 
blended price.” The co-operative payments are subtracted 
prior to the time of the result of the computation of the uni¬ 
form blended price, and the uniformity of that price remains 
unimpaired. 13 The co-operative payments are made without 
in any way being repugnant to the minimum class prices, and 
the uniformity of each class price remains unimpaired. 
Since the Act requires uniformity only with respect to the 
blended price and the class prices, whether high or low, the 
provisions in the order plainly provide that these prices 
shall remain uniform, subject to the adjustments expressly 
authorized by the statute. In this way meaning and signifi¬ 
cance are given to the statutory authorization for the Secre¬ 
tary to include provisions under § 8c(7) (D) of the Act aux¬ 
iliary to those specifically set forth in § 8c(5). 

13 The appellees’ brief, pp. 24-25, incorrectly refers to the butter- 
fat and location adjustments in the Boston order as being sub¬ 
tracted—just the same as co-operative payments—in the com¬ 
putation of the uniform blended price. The order is plain, in 
§ 904.9(d) and § 904.9(e), that the butterfat and location adjust¬ 
ments are made after the uniform blended price has been computed 
and announced, and that those adjustments are, therefore, varia¬ 
tions or exceptions in the uniformity of the blended price. Those 
adjustments are, in that respect, entirely different from the mere 
subtractions for co-operative payments for services performed. 
Also, the uniform blended price is computed (1) as of the 201-210 
mile zone from the marketing area, and (2) on the basis of 3.7% 
butterfat. To make a computation in that manner, butterfat and 
location are relevant in the computation of the uniform blended 
price, e. g., § 904.8(b) (4) of the order. But as “adjustments” or 
variations in the uniformity of tfie blended price, as computed, 
the location and butterfat differentials apply, under §§ 904.9(d) and 
904.9(e), whereas no such variation or adjustment exists for co¬ 
operative payments. 







22 


The appellees’ argument is based on fragments of the 
Act, and fails to recognize that all parts of the statute should 
be considered, compared, and construed together. The stat¬ 
ute as a whole must be considered, in order not to give un¬ 
due effect to particular words or clauses. Helvering v. 
New York Trust Company, 292 U. S. 455, 464; Costanzo v. 
Tillinghast, 287 U. S. 341, 345; and White v. United States, 
305 U. S. 281, 292. In interpreting a statute, “the Court 
will not look merely to a particular clause in which general 
words may be used, but will take in connection with it the 
whole statute . . . and the objects and policy of the law, 
as indicated by its various provisions, and give to it such 
a construction as will carry into execution the will of the 
Legislature, as thus ascertained, according to its true in¬ 
tent and meaning.” Brown v. Duchesne, 19 How. 183, 194. 
The intention of Congress is to be ascertained “not by 
taking the word or clause in question from its setting and 
viewing it apart, but by considering it with the context, the 
general purposes of the statute in which it is found, the 
occasion and circumstances of its use, and other appropriate 
tests for the ascertainment of the legislative will. ’ ’ Helver¬ 
ing v. Stockholms Enskilda Bank, 293 U. S. 84, 93-94. Any 
questions that may arise upon a cursory examination of the 
parts of the statute relied on by the appellees disappear 
when those parts of the Act are read, as they must be, with 
every other material part of the statute and in the light 
of the legislative history. 

HI. Assuming, Arguendo, That the Payments to Co¬ 
operatives Are “ Adjustments” to the Uniform Prices 
in Addition to the Adjustments Expressly Set Forth 
in § 8c(5) (A) and (B), Such Additional Adjustments 
for Co-operative Payments Are Permissible Under 
§ 8c(7) (D) of the Act. 

The appellees argue (appellees’ brief, p. 9) that the 
terms and conditions of a milk order must be found in 
§ 8c(5) of the Act, and that § 8c(5) of the Act enumerates 
certain adjustments that may be made in the uniform class 







23 


prices or in the uniform blended price, and since the 
enumerated adjustments do not include co-operative pay¬ 
ments for market-wide services, there is no statutory au¬ 
thority for the payments to the co-operatives. Assuming, 
arguendo, that the payments to co-operatives are adjust¬ 
ments in the minimum class prices or in the uniform blended 
price, the appellees’ argument fails to give effect to other 
statutory provisions under which the payments to co-opera¬ 
tives are authorized. 

The prefatory statement in § 8c(5) of the Act is decisive 
against limiting the provisions in milk orders to the terms 
and conditions set forth in § 8c(5): 

“In the case of milk and its products, orders issued 
pursuant to this section shall contain one or more of 
the following terms and conditions, and (except as pro¬ 
vided in subsection (7)) no others . . . .” 

Every term or condition in § 8c(5)(A) and (B) of the Act 
is qualified by the introductory passage. The terms and 
conditions in § 8c(5)(A) and (B) of the statute are not all 
the terms and conditions that may be included in a milk 
order; additional provisions may be included under § 8c(7) 
of the Act. Plainly, the terms of the milk order may be 
based on § 8c(5) or on § 8c(7) of the statute. 

The refutation of the appellees’ argument is also found 
in the prefatory passage in § 8c(7) that “orders shall con¬ 
tain one or more” of the terms and conditions set forth in 
§ 8c(7) of the Act. If orders “shall contain” provisions 
under § 8c(7) of the Act, then auxiliary provisions under 
§ 8c(7) may be included in addition to those set forth in 
§ 8c(5). That § 8c(7) of the Act is a proper basis for pro¬ 
visions in a milk order is further emphasized by the statu¬ 
tory provision in subsection (B) of § 8c(7) that the regula¬ 
tory scheme in that subsection shall not apply to milk “sold 
for consumption in fluid form.” Congress must have in¬ 
tended that the various subsections in § 8c(7) may be the 
statutory basis for a provision in a milk order, otherwise 
Congress would not have specified in subsection (B) of 
§ 8c(7) that the particular method of regulation in that 




24 


subsection cannot be applicable to milk * ‘ sold for consump¬ 
tion in fluid form. ’ ’ 

Other provisions of the Act likewise make it clear that 
§ 8c(5) does not set forth all the terms and conditions to be 
incorporated in a milk order. In § 10 of the statute, it is 
provided in subsection (b) that: 

“Each order relating to milk and its products is¬ 
sued by the Secretary under this title shall provide that 
each handler subject thereto shall pay to any authority 
or agency established under such order such handler’s 
pro rata share ... of such expenses as the Sec¬ 
retary may find will necessarily be incurred by such 
authority or agency . . . for the maintenance and 
functioning of such authority or agency. . . .” 

The statute, as a whole, is plain that the provisions 
of a milk order are not limited to those set forth in 
§ 8c(5) of the statute. It is provided in § 8c(7) that a milk 
order shall contain one or more of the terms and conditions 
set forth in that section; and the authorization in subsec¬ 
tion (D) of § Sc(7) is that a milk order may include terms 
or conditions that are “incidental to, and not inconsistent 
with, the terms and conditions specified in subsections (5), 
(6), and (7) and necessary to effectuate the other provi¬ 
sions of such order.” This reference in § 8c(7)(D) to sub¬ 
section (5) of §8(c) constitutes specific and unequivocal 
statutory direction that auxiliary provisions may be in¬ 
cluded in addition to those enumerated in ^ Sc(5). The 
statute, in its entirety, is plain that a milk order shall con¬ 
tain provisions based on § 8c(5), §8c(7), and § 10(b) of 
the Act. 

In analyzing the Act and sustaining its constitutionality, 
it was held in United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative , 
Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 575-576, that under §8c(7) of the Act 
provisions may be included in a milk order that are “auxili¬ 
ary to those definitely specified” in §8c(5) of the statute, 
and the terms or conditions in a milk order may, therefore, 
be based on the statutory authorizations “set out in 
§ 8c(5) and (7).” This interpretation of the Act is con- 


25 


sonant with the principle that meaning and significance 
should be given to each provision in the statute. Ex parte 
Public Bank, 278 U. S. 101,104; Ginsberg & Sons v. Popkin, 
285 U. S. 204, 208; Costmzo v. Tillimghast, 287 U. S. 341, 
345; and White v. United States, 305 U. S. 281, 292. 

Each provision in §8c(5)(A) and (B) of the Act is to 
be read as qualified (1) by the introductory provision in 
§8c(5) that “except as provided in subsection (7)” milk 
orders are limited to the terms and conditions, including the 
adjustments, set forth in §8c(5) of the Act, and (2) 
by the introductory provision in §8c(7) that an order 
“shall contain” one or more of the terms and conditions set 
forth in §8c(7). Hence, the reference in subsections (A) 
and (B) of §Sc(5) to the adjustments therein set forth as 
being the “only” adjustments means that those are the only 
adjustments “except as provided in subsection (7)” of 
§ 8c of the statute. This gives meaning and significance to 
all the statutory provisions, including the prefatory pas¬ 
sages in § 8c(5) and § 8c(7) of the Act; and those explicit 
statutory statements constitute a part of the very substance 
of the Act and must be given effect precisely as any other 
provision. The appellees’ argument in this respect would, 
if adopted, conflict with United States v. Rock Royal Co¬ 
operative, Inc., 307 U. S. 533, 575-576, holding that provi¬ 
sions under subsection (D) of §8c(7) may be included in 
milk orders if the additional provisions are “auxiliary to 
those definitely specified” in § 8c(5) of the Act. 

The statute expressly sets forth certain provisions 
that cannot be included in milk orders. Those prohibited 
provisions, as explained in our main brief, pp. 28-29, con¬ 
stitute the only provisions which, as a matter of law, can¬ 
not be included, on the basis of evidence at a public hearing, 
as being incidentally necessary. These prohibitions in 
the statute give confirmation to the construction that addi¬ 
tional adjustments are permissible under §8c(7)(D) of 
the Act. In short, the Act vests in the Secretary discretion 
commensurate with the legislative goal. Cf. Secretary of 
Agriculture v. Central Roig Refining Company, 338 U. S. 

, 70 S. Ct. 403, 94 L. Ed. 297, decided on February 6, 1950. 



26 


The case of State v. Dairy Distributors, 217 Wis. 167, 258 
X.W. 3S6, relied on by the appellees (appellees’ brief, p. 21), 
relates to issues different in decisive respects from the 
issues under the Boston order and the Act authorizing the 
Boston order. The milk order issued bv the State authori- 
ties, acting under a statute quite different from the Federal 
Act, contained no finding as to any necessity for the assess¬ 
ment alleged to be an unlawful exaction, and the Court em¬ 
phasized (217 Wis. at 170, 258 N.W. at 388) that “We are 
in no way enlightened as to what relation this contribution 
has to the maintenance of the price of milk,” and the “com¬ 
mission nowhere finds that the imposition of such an exac¬ 
tion is necessary.” Moreover, in that criminal proceed¬ 
ing under the Wisconsin statute, the Court held that, “No 
finding is made as to the jurisdictional facts which must ex¬ 
ist as a condition of exercising the power delegated” under 
the state statute. That case has no bearing on the issues now 
presented as to co-operative payments, for services found by 
the Secretary to be necessary, under the Boston order. 

IV. The Boston Milk Order Is Explicit in Requiring the 
Performance of Market-Wide Services by the Co¬ 
operatives That Receive the Payments, and the Ap¬ 
pellees’ Criticism of the Order in This Respect Fails 
to Refer to Other Significant Provisions in the Order. 

The appellees assert (appellees’ brief, pp. 4-5) that the 
services of a co-operative for which payments are received 
under the order are “primarily, and almost exclusively, to 
its owm members;” and the appellees seem to find signifi¬ 
cance in the asserted failure of the order to itemize or 
enumerate all of the various market-wide services to be 
performed by a co-operative that receives payments under 
the order. The appellees’ brief is based, in this respect, on 
only a part of the provisions of the order with respect 
to co-operative payments, and fails to take into considera¬ 
tion other significant provisions in the order with respect to 
co-operative payments for market-wide services. 








27 


The appellees refer only to subsection (a) of §904.10 
of the order. 14 That subsection, however, is related to and 
interlaced with the immediately following subsection, viz., 
subsection (b) of § 904.10, in which different rates of pay¬ 
ment are provided for. 15 The different rates of payment set 
forth in § 904.10(b) relate to different marketing services. 
The higher rate is generally descriptive of the service of a 
co-operative in operating a manufacturing plant at which 
surplus milk is received. The lower rate is generally 
descriptive of bargaining co-operatives. The difference in 
the rates of payment reflects the different levels of market¬ 
wide services performed by the two types of co-operatives. 
The higher rate is designed as partial compensation to the 
operating co-operatives for the greater cost incurred in 
rendering the higher level of services. 

Any co-operative that receives payment under the order is 
required to collaborate with similar associations in the 
classification, pricing, and pooling of milk under the order, 
and payments are suspended by the Secretary whenever he 
has reason to believe that the co-operative is not performing 
the requisite services. 16 The co-operatives are required 
to maintain a competent staff of economists and other ex- 

14 This section of the order is in the Appendix to this brief, 
injra, pp. 40-41. 

13 This section of the order is in the Appendix to this brief, 
infra, pp. 41-42. 

16 The qualifications of co-operative associations are under con¬ 
stant scrutiny by the Secretary, and a co-operative that fails to 
render the market-wide services is suspended and thereby denied 
the right to receive co-operative payments. See, e.g., In the Matter 
of Bethel Cooperative Creamery, Inc., a ruling on May 31, 1945, 
under the Boston order; and under the New York order, In the 
Matter of Sullivan County Cooperative Dairy Association, Inc., 
and New York State Guernsey Breeders’ Cooperative, Inc., rulings 
of January 13, 1950, and September 2, 1943, respectively. In other 
instances applications for payments have been denied after in¬ 
vestigation, e.g., In the Matter of Vermont Co-operative Creamery, 
Inc., under the Boston order, determined June 22, 1945, and In 
the Matter of Crowley’s Milk Producers Cooperative Association, 
Inc., under the New York order, determined September 28, 1948. 
These and other similar determinations are public records on file 
in the office of the Hearing Clerk, U. S. Department of Agriculture, 
Washington, D. C. 





28 


perts for dealing: with marketing problems and for provid¬ 
ing information with respect to these problems. In provid¬ 
ing this information by means of radio programs, and at 
public meetings which are attended by nonmembers as well 
as by members of the co-operatives, and in presenting data 
at public hearings on amendments to the Boston order, it 
is manifest that the services are market-wide in character. 
In maintaining and operating manufacturing plants for 
surplus milk, it is uncontroverted by the appellees that 
the co-operatives are performing services which are of 
benefit to all producers in the milkshed. 

The bill of complaint asserts the absence of any statutory 
authority for co-operative payments, and not the mere fail¬ 
ure to be explicit in the order. The appellees question the 
authority under the statute, not the failure to be explicit in 
the order. If this is merely an instance in which the order 
should be more explicit in setting forth the market-wide 
services to be performed by the co-operatives, the asserted 
defect has no relevance to the statutory authority to pro¬ 
vide, in such orders, for payments to co-operatives for 
market-wide services. 

Moreover, the appellees (appellees’ brief, p. 35) do not 
question the adequacy of the evidence to support the Sec¬ 
retary's finding that the provisions in the order for pay¬ 
ments to co-operatives are necessary in order to effectuate 
the declared policy of the Act. If the appellees are now to 
question whether these services, as set forth in the order, 
are necessary to effectuate the declared policy of the Act, 
a review of the hearing record is called for. The appellees 
disclaim the necessity for any such review. 17 The hearing 
record on which the present order provisions are based is 


17 The references in the appellees’ brief, pp. 17, 20, and 21, to 
the co-operative payments as being bounties, subsidies, or subven¬ 
tions is entirely irrelevant in view of the appellees’ failure to assert 
an absence of substantial evidence to support the Secretary’s find¬ 
ings. As to whether the payments are bounties, subsidies, or sub¬ 
ventions depends on the services performed and the necessity for 
the services; all of this can be resolved only on the basis of whether 
substantial evidence supports the Secretary’s findings on the basis 
of the evidence adduced at the public hearing. 






29 


not before the Court. There can be no merit, therefore, in 
the appellees’ criticisms of the provisions in the order 
with respect to the types of services to be performed by 
the co-operatives who qualify for payments under the 
order. 

V. The Scope of Judicial Review is Limited, and the 
Validity of the Provisions for Payments to Co-opera¬ 
tives Depends on Whether Substantial Evidence in 
the Hearing Record Supports the Secretary’s Find¬ 
ings. The Hearing Record on Which the Present 
Order Provisions are Based is Not Before This Court 
and, Therefore, Since the Provisions for Co-operative 
Payments are Not Prohibited by the Act, There Ccm 
Be No Holding That the Provisions Are Invalid. 

The amendment to the Boston milk order effective August 
1, 1941, providing for payments to co-operatives, contains 
a finding of fact by the Secretary, on the basis of the amend¬ 
ment hearing, that the provisions of the order for co-opera¬ 
tive payments are necessary to the effectuation of the classi¬ 
fication, pricing, and pooling provisions in the order. These 
provisions of the order were amended again effective August 
1, 1947, and the finding by the Secretary is that each of the 
provisions in the amendment is necessary in order to effect¬ 
uate the declared purpose of the Act. The appellees’ brief 
suggests (appellees’ brief, p. 36) that the amendments ef¬ 
fective August 1, 1947, provide for only a few procedural 
or trivial changes in the order and that, therefore, no 
significance should be attached to the failure to include the 
hearing record on which those amendments were based as 
a part of the record in this litigation. 

The notice of the hearing on which the 1947 amendments 
were based refutes the appellees’ contentions that only in¬ 
consequential aspects of the co-operative payment provi¬ 
sions were dealt with at the hearing. The notice of hearing 
(11 F.R. 640, 643-644) sets forth seven proposals with 
respect to payments to co-operatives. Some of those pro¬ 
posals deal with changes in the rates of payment, but 
one of the proposals is to delete all of the provisions of the 








30 


order for payments to co-operatives, and another proposal 
is to reconsider, in all respects, the co-operative payment 
provisions of the order. The issues created by these pro¬ 
posals, on which that hearing was held, were strongly con¬ 
tested and thoroughly considered at the public hearing held 
in Febraarv and March 1946. The evidence adduced at the ' 
hearing with respect to the issues relative to co-operative 
payments is found in 472 pages of testimony and 33 ex¬ 
hibits. 18 On the basis of the evidence adduced at that hear¬ 
ing, the Secretary issued an amendment (12 F.R. 4921) 
which completely revised the co-operative payment pro¬ 
visions of the order. 19 

The findings of the Secretary on the basis of the evidence 
at a public hearing carry a presumption of the existence 
of a state of facts justifying the action. United States v. 
Rock Royal , Inc., 307 U.S. 533, 567-568; Thompson v. Con¬ 
solidated Gas Utilities Corporation , 300 U.S. 55, 69; Wallace 
v. Hudson-Duncan & Compamy (C. A. 9), 98 F. 2d 985; and 
Qucensboro Farms Products v. Wickard (C. A. 2), 137 F. 

2d 969, 977-9S1. The administrative interpretation of the 
Act is entitled to great weight, and: “This is peculiarly 
true here where the interpretations involve ‘contempora¬ 
neous construction of a statute by the men charged with 
the responsibility of setting its machinery in motion, of 


18 The transcript of the record of this hearing is a public record 
in the Office of the Hearing Clerk, U. S. Department of Agriculture, 
Washington, D. C., and is identified as Docket No. AO-14-A12, 
and the evidence with respect to co-operative payments is found 
in pp. 1621-2,093. 

19 The original provision for the payment of 1.5 cents per hundred¬ 
weight on all milk marketed by a qualified co-operative on behalf 
of its members was changed to 1 cent per hundredweight on such 
milk as its members delivered to handlers other than a qualified 
co-operative. The original payment of 5 cents per hundredweight 
to co-operatives operating their own plants for milk received from 
producers at such plants and sold as Class I milk to proprietary 
handlers was changed to a payment of 2 cents per hundredweight 
on milk received from producers at plants operated by qualified 
co-operatives. Many other changes were also effectuated in the 
provisions of the order dealing with payments to co-operatives. 
These changes are discussed in the report which was published in 
the Federal Register (12 F.R. 1169) on February 20, 1947. 


I 







31 


making the parts work efficiently and smoothly while- they 
are yet untried and new.’ ” United States v. American 
Trucking Association, 310 U.S. 534, 549. See also Cardillo 
v. Liberty Mutual Insurance Company, 330 U.S. 469, 477; 
Unemployment Compensation Commission v. Aragon, 329 
U. S. 143, 153-154; Roland Electrical Company v. Walling, 
326 U. S. 657,676; National Labor Relations Board v. Hearst 
Publications, Inc., 322 U.S. Ill, 131; and Colgate Company 
v. United States, 320 U.S. 422, 426. Any such interpretation 
will not ‘ ‘ be overturned unless clearly wrong, or unless a dif¬ 
ferent construction is plainly required.” United States v. 
Jackson, 280 U.S. 183,193. Moreover, the rule that a special¬ 
ized agency’s findings on a question within its specialty “are 
not to be disturbed except in the plainest case • • • 

applies here with a special force just because the findings 
are necessarily prospective; time alone [could] decide their 
success or their failure.” Philadelphia Company v. Securi¬ 
ties and Exchange Commission, App. D.C. , 177 F. 2d 
720, 724. 

The hearing record on which the 1947 amendments are 
based is not before the Court. The appellees failed to sub¬ 
mit that hearing record in this proceeding in the District 
Court. That forecloses any question as to the validity of 
these provisions in the Boston milk order. Shields v. Utah 
Idaho Central R. Co., 305 U.S. 177. 

CONCLUSION 

For the foregoing reasons the judgment of the lower court 
should be reversed and the amended complaint should be 
dismissed. 

J. Stephen Doyle, Jr., 

Neil Brooks, 

Special Assistants to the Attorney General . 

Lewis A. Sigler, 

Assistant Associate Solicitor. 

Mary Connor Myers, 

Attorney, U. S. Department of 
Agriculture. 




32 


APPENDIX 

The following are relevant sections of the Agricultural 
Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (7 U.S.C. 601 et seq.): 

§ 60Sc. Orders Regulating Handling of Commodity. 

(1) Issuance by Secretary. 

Sec. 8c. (1) The Secretary of Agriculture shall, subject 
to the provisions of this section, issue, and from time to 
time amend, orders applicable to processors, associations 
of producers, and others engaged in the handling of any 
agricultural commodity or product thereof specified in sub¬ 
section (2) of this section. Such orders shall regulate, in 
the manner hereinafter in this section provided, only such 
handling of such agricultural commodity, or product 
thereof, as is in the current of interstate or foreign com¬ 
merce, or which directly burdens, obstructs, or affects, inter¬ 
state or foreign commerce in such commodity or product 
thereof. 

• •••«•• 

(3) Notice and Hearing. 

(3) Whenever the Secretary of Agriculture has reason to 
believe that the issuance of an order will tend to effectuate 
the declared policy of this title with respect to any com¬ 
modity or product thereof specified in subsection (2) of 
this section, he shall give due notice of and an opportunity 
for a hearing upon a proposed order. 

(4) Finding and Issuance of Order. 

(4) After such notice and opportunity for hearing, the 
Secretary of Agriculture shall issue an order if he finds, 
and sets forth in such order, upon the evidence introduced 
at such hearing (in addition to such other findings as may 
be specifically required by this section) that the issuance 
of such order and all of the terms and conditions thereof 
will tend to effectuate the declared policy of this title with 
respect to such commodity. 

(5) Milk and Its Products; Terms and Conditions of Orders 

(5) In the case of milk and its products, orders issued 
pursuant to this section shall contain one or more of the 
following terms and conditions, and (except as provided in 
subsection (7)) no others: 

(A) Classifying milk in accordance with the form in 
which or the purpose for which it is used, and fixing, or pro- 




33 


viding a method for fixing, minimum prices for each such 
use classification which all handlers shall pay, and the time 
when payments shall be made, for milk purchased from 
producers or associations of producers. Such prices shall 
be uniform as to all handlers, subject only to adjustments 
for (1) volume, market, and production differentials cus¬ 
tomarily applied by the handlers subject to such order, 
(2) the grade or quality of the milk purchased, and (3) 
the locations at which delivery of such milk, or any use 
classification thereof, is made to such handlers. 

(B) Providing: 

(i) for the payment to all producers and associa¬ 
tions of producers delivering milk to the same handler 
of uniform prices for all milk delivered by them: Pro¬ 
vided, That, except in the case of orders covering milk 
products only, such provision is approved or favored 
by at least three-fourths of the producers who, during 
a representative period determined by the Secretary 
of Agriculture, have been engaged in the production 
for market of milk covered in such order or by pro¬ 
ducers who, during such representative period, have 
produced at least three-fourths of the volume of such 
milk produced for market during such period; the 
approval required hereunder shall be separate and 
apart from any other approval or disapproval provided 
for by this section; or 

(ii) for the payment to all producers and associa¬ 
tions of producers delivering milk to all handlers of 
uniform prices for all milk so delivered, irrespec¬ 
tive of the uses fnade of such milk by the individual 
handler to whom it is delivered; 

subject, in either case, only to adjustments for (a) volume, 
market, and production differentials customarily applied 
by the handlers subject to such order, (b) the grade or 
quality of the milk delivered, (c) the locations at which 
delivery of such milk is made, and (d) a further adjust¬ 
ment, equitably to apportion the total value of the milk pur¬ 
chased bv any handler, or by all handlers, among producers 
and associations of producers, on the basis of their mar¬ 
ketings of milk during a representative period of time. 

(C) In order to accomplish the purposes set forth in 
paragraphs (A) and (B) of this subsection (5), provid¬ 
ing a method for making adjustments in payments, as among 



34 


handlers (including producers who are also handlers), to 
the end that the total sums paid by each handler shall equal 
the value of the milk purchased by him at the prices fixed 
in accordance with paragraph (A) hereof. 

(D) Providing that, in the case of all milk purchased by 
handlers from any producer who did not regularly sell milk 
during a period of 30 days next preceding the effective date 
of such order for consumption in the area covered thereby, 
payments to such producer, for the period beginning with 
the first regular delivery by such producer and continuing 
until the end of two full calendar months following the 
first day of the next succeeding calendar month, shall be 
made at the price for the lowest use classification specified 
in such order, subject to the adjustments specified in para¬ 
graph (B) of this subsection (5). 

(E) Providing (i) except as to producers for whom such 
services are being rendered by a cooperative marketing 
association, qualified as provided in paragraph (F) of this 
subsection (5), for market information to producers and 
for the verification of weights, sampling, and testing of 
milk purchased from producers, and for making appro¬ 
priate deductions therefor from payments to producers, 
and (ii) for assurance of, and security for, the payment by 
handlers for milk purchased. 

(F) Nothing contained in this subsection (5) is intended 
or shall be construed to prevent a cooperative marketing 
association qualified under the provisions of the Act of 
Congress of February 18, 1922, as amended, known as the 
“Capper-Volstead Act,” engaged in making collective sales 
or marketing of milk or its products for the producers 
thereof, from blending the net proceeds of all its sales in 
all markets in all use classifications, and making distribu¬ 
tion thereof to its producers in accordance with the contract 
between the association and its producers: Provided, That 
it shall not sell milk or its products to any handler for use 
or consumption in any market at prices less than the prices 
fixed pursuant to paragraph (A) of this subsection (5) 
for such milk. 

(G) No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk 
and its products in any marketing area shall prohibit or in 
any manner limit, in the case of the products of milk, the 
marketing in that area of any milk or product thereof 
produced in any production area in the United States. 

• •••••• 






35 


(7) Terms Common to All Orders. 

(7) In the case of the agricultural commodities and the 
products thereof specified in subsection (2) orders shall 
contain one or more of the following terms and conditions: 

(A) Prohibiting unfair methods of competition and un¬ 
fair trade practices in the handling thereof. 

(B) Providing that (except for milk and cream to be sold 
for consumption in fluid form) such commodity or product 
thereof, or any grade, size, or quality thereof shall be sold 
by the handlers thereof only at prices filed by such handlers 
in the manner provided in such order. 

(C) Providing for the selection by the Secretary of Agri¬ 
culture, or a method for the selection, of an agency or agen¬ 
cies and defining their power and duties, which shall include 
only the powers: 

(i) To administer such order in accordance with its 
terms and provisions; 

(ii) To make rules and regulations to effectuate the 
terms and provisions of such order; 

(iii) To receive, investigate, and report to the Secre¬ 
tary of Agriculture complaints of violations of such 
order; and 

(iv) To recommend to the Secretary of Agriculture 
amendments to such order. 

No person acting as a member of an agency established pur¬ 
suant to this paragraph (C) shall be deemed to be acting in 
an official capacity, within the meaning of section 10 (g) 
of this title, unless such person receives compensation for 
his personal services from funds of the United States. 

(D) Incidental to, and not inconsistent with, the terms 
and conditions specified in subsections (5), (6), and (7) and 
necessary to effectuate the other provisions of such order. 

• •••••• 

§ 610. Administration Generally. 

Sec. 10(b)(2). Each order relating to milk and its 
products issued by the Secretary under this title shall pro¬ 
vide that each handler subject thereto shall pay to any 
authority or agency established under such order such 
handler’s pro rata share (as approved by the Secretary) 




36 


of such expenses as the Secretary may find will necessarily 
be incurred by such authority or agency, during any period 
specified by him, for the maintenance and functioning of 
such authority or agency, other than expenses incurred in 
receiving, handling, holding, or disposing of any quantity of 
milk or products thereof received, handled, held, or dis¬ 
posed of by such authority or agency for the benefit or 
account of persons other than handlers subject to such order. 
The pro rata share of the expenses payable by a coopera¬ 
tive association of producers shall be computed on the 
basis of the quantity of milk or product thereof covered by 
such order which is distributed, processed, or shipped by 
such cooperative association of producers. 

In issuing the amended order effective August 1, 1941, 
the Secretarv made the following findings of fact (6 F. R. 
3762, 7 CFR,' 1941 Supp., §904.0): 

“(a) The Secretary finds, upon the evidence intro¬ 
duced at the hearings, said findings being in addition 
to the findings made upon the evidence introduced at 
the original hearings on this order, and on amendments 
to said order, and being in addition to the other findings 
and determinations made prior to or at the time of the 
original issuance of said order and of amendments 
thereto (which findings are hereby ratified and affirmed 
save only as such findings are in conflict with the find¬ 
ings hereinafter set forth) ; • 

“ (3) That the provisions relating to the payments out 
of the equalization pool to cooperative associations per¬ 
forming certain marketing services are incidental to, 
not inconsistent with, the other provisions of this order, 
as amended, and necessary to effectuate the other provi¬ 
sions of the order, as amended; * * # 

“(6) That the issuance of this order, as amended, 
and all of its terms and conditions will tend to effectuate 
the declared policy of the act * # 

In issuing the amended order effective August 1, 1947, 
the Secretary made the following findings of fact (12 F. R. 
4921, 7 CFR, 1941 Supp., 904—Appendix): 

“(a) Findings * * * upon the basis of the evi¬ 
dence introduced at such hearings and the record 
thereof, it is found that: 

(1) The said order, as amended, and as hereby fur¬ 
ther amended, and all of the terms and conditions of 






37 


said order, as amended and as hereby further amended, 
will tend to effectuate the declared policy of the 
act; # # * 

“The foregoing findings are supplementary and in addi¬ 
tion to the findings made in connection with the issuance of 
the aforesaid order and the findings made in connection with 
the issuance of each of the previously issued amendments 
thereto; and all of said previous findings are hereby ratified 
and affirmed except insofar as such findings may be in con¬ 
flict with the findings set forth herein.” 

The following are relevant sections of the Boston milk 
marketing order, as amended (12 F.R. 4921, 7 CFR, 1947 
Supp., 904.0 et seq.): 

§ 904.8 Minimum blended prices to producers —(a) Com¬ 
putation of value of milk received from producers. For 
each month, the market administrator shall compute the 
value of milk received from producers which is sold, dis¬ 
tributed, or used by each pool handler, in the following 
manner: 

(1) Multiply the quantity of milk in each class by the 
price applicable pursuant to § 904.7 (a) and (b); 

(2) Add together the resulting value of each class; and 

(3) Adjust the value determined in subparagraph (2) of 
this paragraph as provided in § 904.7 (d). 

(b) Computation of the basic blended price. The market 
administrator shall compute the basic blended price per 
hundredweight of milk delivered during each month in the 
following manner: 

(1) Combine into one total the respective values of milk, 
computed pursuant to paragraph (a) of this section, for each 
pool handler from whom the market administrator has re¬ 
ceived at his office, prior to the 11th day after the end of 
such month, the report for such month and the payments 
required pursuant to § 904.9 (b)(2) and (g) for milk re¬ 
ceived during each month since the effective date of the most 
recent amendment of this part; 

(2) Add the total amount of payments required from 
handlers pursuant to § 904.9 (g); 

(3) Add the amount of unreserved cash on hand at the 
close of business on the 10th day after the end of the month 
from payments made to the market administrator by han¬ 
dlers pursuant to § 904.9; 

(4) Deduct the amount of the plus differentials, and add 
the amount of the minus differentials, which are appli¬ 
cable pursuant to § 904.9 (e); 



38 


(5) Subtract the total amount of co-operative payments 
required by § 904.10 (b); 

(6) Divide by the total quantity of milk for which a value 
is determined pursuant to subparagraph (1) of this para¬ 
graph ; and 

(7) Subtract not less than 4 cents nor more than 5 cents 
for the purpose of retaining a cash balance in connection 
with the payments set forth in § 904.9. This result shall be 
known as the basic blended price for milk containing 3.7 
percent butterfat. 

(c) Announcement of blended prices. On the 12th day 
after the end of each month the market administrator shall 
mail to all pool handlers and shall publicly announce: 

(1) Such of these computations as do not disclose in¬ 
formation confidential pursuant to the act; 

(2) The zone blended prices per hundredweight resulting 
from adjustment of the basic blended price by the differen¬ 
tials pursuant to § 904.9 (e); and 

(3) The names of the pool handlers, designating those 
whose milk is not included in the computations. 

§ 904.9 Payments for milk —(a) Advance payments. On 
or before the 10th day after the end of each month, each 
pool handler shall make payment to producers for the ap¬ 
proximate value of milk received during the first 15 days 
of such month. In no event shall such advance payment 
be at a rate less than the Class II price for such month. 
The provisions of this paragraph shall not apply to any 
handler who, on or before the 17th day after the end of the 
month, makes final payment as required by subparagraph 
(1) of paragraph (b) of this section. 

(b) Final payments. On or before the 25th day after the 
end of each month, each pool handler shall make payment 
for the total value of milk received during such month as 
required to be computed pursuant to § 904.8 (a), as follows: 

(1) To each producer at not less than the basic blended 
price per hundredweight, subject to the differentials pro¬ 
vided in paragraphs (d) and (e) of this section, for the 
quantitv of milk delivered by such producer; and 

(2) To producers, through the market administrator, by 
paying to, on or before the 23d day after the end of each 
month, or receiving from the market administrator, on or 
before the 25th day after the end of each month, as the case 
may be, the amount by which the payments required to be 
made pursuant to subparagraph (1) of this paragraph are 
less than or exceed the value of milk as required to be com¬ 
puted for such handler pursuant to $ 904.8 (a), as shown 



39 


in a statement rendered by the market administrator on or 
before the 20th day after the end of such month. 

(c) Adjustments of errors in payments . Whenever veri¬ 
fication by the market administrator of reports or payments 
of any handler discloses errors made in payments pursuant 
to subparagraph (2) of paragraph (b) of this section, the 
market administrator shall promptly bill such handler for 
any unpaid amount and such handler shall, within 15 days, 
make payment to the market administrator of the amount 
so billed. Whenever verification discloses that payment 
is payable by the market administrator to any handler, the 
market administrator shall, within 15 days, make such pay¬ 
ment to such handler. Whenever verification by the market 
administrator of the payment to any producer for milk 
delivered to any handler discloses payment to such pro¬ 
ducer of an amount less than is required by this section, the 
handler shall make up such payment to the producer not 
later than the time of making final payment for the month in 
which such error is disclosed. 

(d) Butterfat differential. Each pool handler shall, in 
making the payments to each producer for milk received 
from him, add for each one-tenth of 1 percent of average 
butterfat content above 3.7 percent or deduct for each one- 
tenth of 1 percent of average butterfat content below 3.7 
per cent an amount per hundredweight which shall be cal¬ 
culated by the market administrator as follows: divide by 
33.48 the weighted average price per 40-quart can of 40 
percent bottling quality cream, f. o. b. Boston, as reported 
bv the United States Department of Agriculture for the 
period between the 16th day of the preceding month and the 
15th day inclusive of the month during which such milk is 
delivered, subtract 1.5 cents, and divide the result by 10: 
Provided, That if no such cream price is reported, multiply 
the average price reported for such period by the United 
States Department of Agriculture for U. S. Grade A (U. S. 
92-score) butter at wholesale in the Chicago market by 1.4, 
subtract 1.5 cents, and divide the result by 10. 

(e) Location differentials. The payments to be made to 
producers by handlers pursuant to subparagraph (1) of 
paragraph (b) of this section shall be subject to the differ¬ 
entials set forth in Column B of the table in $ 904.7 (c), and 
to further differentials as follows: 

(1) With respect to milk delivered by a producer whose 
farm is located more than 40 miles but not more than 80 
miles from the State House in Boston, there shall be added 




40 


23 cents per hundredweight, unless such addition gives a 
result greater than the Class I price pursuant to § 904.7 (a) 
and (c) which is effective at the plant to which such milk is 
delivered, in which event there shall be added an amount 
which will give as a result such price. 

(2) 'With respect to milk delivered by a producer whose 
farm is located not more than 40 miles from the State House 
in Boston, there shall be added 46 cents per hundredweight, 
unless such addition gives a result greater than the Class 
I price pursuant to §904.7 (a) and (c) which is effective 
at the plant to which such milk is delivered, in which event 
there shall be added an amount which will give as a result 
such price. 

(f) Other differentials. In making the payments to pro¬ 
ducers set forth in subparagraph (1) of paragraph (b) of 
this section, pool handlers may make deductions as follows: 

(1) With respect to milk delivered by producers to a 
city plant which is located outside the marketing area and 
more than 14 miles from the State House in Boston, 10 
cents per hundredweight; 

(2) With respect to milk delivered by producers to a 
country plant, at which plant the average daily receipts of 
milk from producers are: 

(i) Less than 17,000 but greater than 8,500 pounds, 4 
cents per hundredweight; and 

(ii) 8,500 pounds or less, 8 cents per hundredweight. 

• •••••• 

§ 904.10 Payment to cooperative associations —(a) Appli¬ 
cation and qualification for cooperative payments. Any 
cooperative association of producers duly organized under 
the laws of any state may apply to the Secretary for a deter¬ 
mination that it is qualified to receive cooperative payments 
in accordance with the provisions of this section. Upon 
notice of the filing of such an application, the market admin¬ 
istrator shall set aside for each month, from the funds pro¬ 
vided by handlers’ payments to the market administrator 
pursuant to § 904.9, such amount as he estimates is ample 
to make payment to the applicant, and hold it in reserve 
until the Secretary has ruled upon the application. The 
applicant association shall be considered to be a qualified 
association entitled to receive such payments from the 
date fixed by the Secretary, if he determines that it meets 
all of the following requirements. 


41 


(1) It conforms to the requirements relating to charac¬ 
ter of organization, voting, dividend payments, and dealing 
in products of nonmembers, which are set forth in the 
Capper-Volstead Act and in the state laws under which the 
association is organized. 

(2) It operates as a responsible producer-controlled 
marketing association exercising full authority in the sale 
of the milk of its members. 

(3) It systematically checks the weights and tests of milk 
which its members deliver to plants not operated by the 
association. 

(4) It guarantees payment to its members for milk deliv¬ 
ered to plants not operated by the association. 

(5) It maintains, either individually or together with 
other qualified associations, a competent staff for dealing 
with marketing problems and for providing information to 
its members. 

(6) It constantly maintains close working relationships 
with its members. 

(7) It collaborates with similar associations in activities 
incident to the maintenance and strengthening of collective 
bargaining by producers and the operation of a plan of uni¬ 
form pricing of milk to handlers. 

(8) It is in compliance with all applicable provisions of 
this order. 

(b) Cooperative Payments. On or before the 25th day 
after the end of each month, each qualified association shall 
be entitled to receive a cooperative payment from the funds 
provided by handlers’ payments to the market administra¬ 
tor pursuant to § 904.9. The payment shall be made under 
the conditions and at the rates specified in this paragraph, 
and shall be subject to verification of the receipts and other 
items upon which such payment is based. 

(1) Each qualified association shall be entitled to pay¬ 
ment at the rate of 1 cent per hundredweight on the milk 
which its producer members deliver to the plant of a hand¬ 
ler other than a qualified association; except on milk deliv¬ 
ered by a producer who is also a member of another quali¬ 
fied association, and on milk delivered to a handler who 
fails to make applicable payments pursuant to § 904.9 (b)(2) 
and § 904.11 within 10 days after the end of the month in 
which he is required to do so. If the handler is required 
by paragraph (e) of this section to make deductions from 
members of the association at a rate lower than 1 cent per 





42 


hundredweight, the payment pursuant to this subparagraph 
shall be at such lower rate. 

(2) Each qualified association shall be entitled to pay¬ 
ment at the rate of 2 cents per hundredweight on milk re¬ 
ceived from producers at a plant operated by that associa¬ 
tion. 

(c) Reports relating to cooperative payments. Each 
qualified association shall, upon request by the market 
administrator, make reports to him with respect to its use 
of cooperative payments and its performance in meeting the 
requirements set forth as the basis for such payments, and 
shall file with him a copy of its balance sheet and operating 
statement at the close of each fiscal year. 

(d) Suspension of cooperative payments. Whenever 
there is reason to believe that an association is no longer 
meeting the qualification requirements, the market admin¬ 
istrator shall, upon request by the Secretary, suspend co¬ 
operative payments to it, and shall give the association writ¬ 
ten notice of the suspension. Such suspended payments 
shall be held in reserve until the Secretary has, after notice 
and opportunity for a hearing, ruled upon the performance 
of the association. 

(e) Deductions from payments to members. (1) Each 
association which is entitled to receive cooperative pay¬ 
ments on milk which its producer members deliver to a 
handler other than a qualified association may file a claim 
with the handler for amounts to be deducted from the hand¬ 
ler’s payments to such members. The claim shall contain 
a list of the producers, an agreement to indemnify the hand¬ 
ler in the making of the deductions, and a certification that 
the association has an unterminated membership contract 
with each producer, authorizing the claimed deduction. 

(2) In making payments to his producers for milk re¬ 
ceived during the month, each handler shall make deduc¬ 
tions in accordance with the association’s claim, and shall 
pay the amount deducted to the association within 25 days 
after the end of the month. 


☆ U. S. tOVKHNNINT miNTIMC OFFICC; 1*10 


■71741 


Ilf 












Nos. 10,365, 10,366 

REPLY BRIEF FOR APPELLANT 
DAIRYMEN’S LEAGUE CO-OPERATIVE 
ASSOCIATION, INC. 


In The 

Hniteit States ffimtrt of Appeals 

Fob the Distbict of Columbia Circuit 

C~ y - - 

-V 

No. 10,365 ' 

Chables F. Bbannan, Secretary of Agriculture, 

Appellant, 

v. 

Delbebt 0. Stabk, et al.. 

Appellees. 


No. 10,366 

Dairymen’s League Co-Operative Association, Inc., 

Appellant, 

v. 

Delbebt 0. Stabk, et al.. 

Appellees. 


On Appeal from the Judgment of the United States 
District Court for the District of Columbia 


Seward A. Miller 
Frank B. Lent 
New York City 
Attorneys for Appellant, 
Dairymens League Cooper¬ 
ative Association, Inc. 

Of Counsel 


Wm. E. Leahy 
War. J. Hughes, Jb. 
Bowen Building 
Washington, D. C. 


Wilson - Epes Pointing Co. - RE 6003 - Washington 1. D. C. 













INDEX 


PAGE 


A. Appellees Have Confused Methods of Fixing 
Prices to Handlers and Payments to Producers.... 1 

B. The Present Deductions Are Not the Only Deduc¬ 
tions Made from the Producers Generally. 3 

C. The Cooperative Producers Bear the Majority Ex¬ 
pense of the Deduction.. 3 

D. Affidavits Showing Market-Wide Services Were 

Properly Before the Court Below. 4 

E. Findings of the Secretary; “Order’’ and “Act”.. 4 

F. Alleged Omission of Sec. 10(b) (1) in 1937 Act.... 5 

G. Prices to Handlers. 5 

H. Discrimination Against Handlers.... 5 

I. Plaintiffs’ Right to Sue. 6 

J. Provisions for Deductions in New York Statutes.. 6 

K. Other Orders Providing Deductions. 8 















In The 


Imteii States fflnart of Appeala 

For the District of Columbia Circuit 


Nos. 10,365 and 10,366 

Charles F. Brannan, Secretary of Agriculture, 

Appellant, 

v. 

Delbert 0. Stark, et al.. 

Appellees. 

No. 10,366 

Dairymen's League Co-Operative Association, Inc., 

Appellant, 

v. 

Delbert 0. Stark, et al.. 

Appellees. 


On Appeal from the Judgment of the United States 
District Court for the District of Columbia 


REPLY BRIEF FOR APPELLANT 
DAIRYMEN’S LEAGUE CO-OPERATIVE 
ASSOCIATION, INC. 


A. Appellees Have Confused Methods of Fixing Prices 
to Handlers and Payments to Producers: 

In their Brief, p. 24-26, Appellees apparently misunder¬ 
stand the provisions of Order 4 as to fixing prices to han¬ 
dlers, basic blended prices, and payments to producers. 
They treat the last two steps as one, and ignore the real 
difference between them. 




2 


In the first place, the prices to the handlers are those 
fixed in §904.7 of the 1947 Order and 904.4 of the 1941 
Order. In the New York Order of April 1, 1949, there 
is even a separate subdivision for this entitled “Net 
Pool Obligation of Handlers.” (§927.7 (a)). 

After the total value of all milk is obtained from the 
dealer’s report, a uniform price to producers is obtained 
under §904.7 of the 1941 Order and 907.8 of the 1947 
Order. The latter section is headed “Minimum Blended 
Prices to Producers”, and the result obtained after de¬ 
ductions not only of payments to cooperatives, but also 
for reserves, is termed “Basic Blended Price’’ (§904.8 (b) 
(7) of the 1947 Order). Then the provisions for pay¬ 
ment to the individual producers are set forth in §904.9 of 
the 1947 Order and 904.8 of the 1941 Order. Thus we 
have a distinction between deductions which affect the 
basic blended price and those which affect individual pro¬ 
ducers, the latter taking into consideration the adjust¬ 
ments for butterfat, location, etc. which are specifically 
mentioned in §8c (5) (B) (ii) of the Act. However, and 
this is important, the adjustments as to “Basic Blended 
Price” are not referred to in the Act except that the price 
to be paid producers shall be uniform, regardless of the 
uses made bv the handlers to whom the milk was deliv¬ 
ered. Appellee’s fully ignore the distinction as to “Basic 
blended price”. See page 24 of their brief. The basic 
blended price is the Administrator’s blended price. The 
next section of the Order provides for payments to pro¬ 
ducers which are to be made by the handlers, as distin¬ 
guished from the determination of the price by the Ad¬ 
ministrator. Thus, the handlers make the deductions re¬ 
ferred to in the last part of Section 8c (5) (B) (ii) of the 
Act. Naturally the payments by the handlers to the pro¬ 
ducers must be safeguarded. Therefore, the word “only” 
is used in the text of the Act, but it applies to these pay¬ 
ments, and not to the price determination by the Adminis- 



3 


trator. This is shown by the wording of the text in that 
it refers to adjustments customarily applied by the han¬ 
dlers. 

B. The Present Deductions Are Not the Only Deductions 
Made From the Producers Generally: 

The Appellees imply that the deductions for payments 
to cooperative associations are the only deductions made 
under the Boston Order from the producers generally. 
Apparently the trial court accepted this claim. The claim 
is contrary to the facts. Sections 904.7 (7) and (8) of 
the 1941 Order and 904.8 (3) and (7) of the 1947 Order 
specifically provide, in addition to the provisions for co¬ 
operative payments, for additions to and deductions from 
the blending fund for a reserve fund. The basis of these 
reserves is to furnish the Administrator with a capital 
fund to take care of delayed payments by handlers, audited 
adjustments, and improper classification reports. With¬ 
out such capital the blends would necessarily be determined 
by the exact amount due from all handlers regardless of 
payment, but funds would not be available for making the 
required payments and the blend would break down. The 
producers may never receive the full amount thus de¬ 
ducted as in the case of a bankrupt handler. Thus, these 
reserve deductions, made from the basic blended price 
exactly as cooperative deductions, are on the same legal 
basis as the latter. It seems clear that if one is invalid, 
the other is. There is no intention here to object to these 
reserve deductions, and Appellees have at no time in this 
case made objection to, and thereby they accept, a deduc¬ 
tion similar to that to which they object herein. 

C. The Cooperative Producers Bear the Majority Expense 
of the Deduction: 

Appellees in their Brief, p. 17, stress the burden of a 
quarter of the million dollars annually due to deductions 
for payments to cooperatives. However, it should be borne 



4 


in mind that a computation from the table set forth on p. 
250 of the Joint App. shows that approximately 68.6 per 
cent of deliveries of milk were made by producers of co¬ 
operatives, and thus approximately $171,500. of the quar¬ 
ter million dollars is actually borne by such producers. 

D. Affidavits Showing Market-Wide Services Were Prop¬ 
erly Before the Court Below: 

On page 8 of their brief, Appellees apparently claim 
that the proceedings on the Motion for Summary Judg¬ 
ment are not material in this case and hence affidavits as 
to market-wide services cannot be availed of here. It is 
an established rule that an appeal from the final judgment 
in equity case brings up all interlocutory matters. 

Victor Talking Mach. Co. v. George, 105 F. 2nd, 
697,699. 

Western Union. T. Co. v. U. S. & M. T. Co., 221 Fed., 
545,551. 

E. Findings of the Secretary; “Order" and “Act": 

Appellees, in a footnote on page 29, question the findings 
of the Secretary. They cite only finding No. 3 in the 
1941 Order and omit finding No. 6, which was as follows: 

“6. That the issuance of the Order, as amended, and 
all of its terms and conditions, will tend to effectuate 
the declared policy of the Act." 

Again, in the 1947 Order, finding (3) ratifies the findings 
in previous Orders, and finding (1) states that the terms 
and conditions of the Order as amended will tend to ef¬ 
fectuate the declared policy of the Act, and also determi¬ 
nation (2) is as follows: 

“2. The issuance of this amended Order is the only 
practical means, pursuant to the declared policy of 
the Act, of advancing the interests of producers of 
milk which is produced for sale in the said marketing 
area;" 


5 


F. Alleged Omission of Sec. 10(b)(1) in 1937 Act: 

See footnote p. 31. While it is true that §10 (b) (1) 
of the 1935 Act was not expressly re-enacted in 1937, the 
latter Act in §5 expressly retained this provision, and the 
Court in the Rock Royal case, 307 U. S., 533, 563, ex¬ 
pressly held the provisions to be applicable. 

G. Prices to Handlers: 

On p. 26 Appellees refer to the provisions of the Act 
(§8c (5) (C)) as to prices to handlers. Their reasoning 
is erroneous. This provision is to safe guard the policy 
of the Act that the handlers pay only the fair value of 
their milk under the various classes. In other words, he 
should account to the Administrator and the producer on 
the basis of class value, that is, of fluid milk at one price 
and of cream at another price, and butter or cheese at 
another. This is in line with the idea of a classified price 
system, and has no real reference to the determination of 
the basic blended price. 

It is also true that the Administrator is a trustee for 
the producers, and the payments to producers are paid 
to them, through him, under the terms of the Order. This 
may be illustrated by the case of dealer A, who handles 
only Class I milk and who pays the difference between 
such Class I price and the basic blend price to the Ad¬ 
ministrator, and of dealer B, whose milk is used largely 
as Class II and w T ho receives money from the Administra¬ 
tor so that he can pay his producers, and both A and B 
then pay the producers on the basis of the basic blended 
price. Thus payment is made to a considerable extent 
through the Administrator. 

H. Discrimination Against Handlers: 

The statement in Appellant’s brief, in the last sentence 
of Point III on page 33, seems clearly inaccurate. There 
was a colloquy in the Senate between Chairman Smith, of 







6 


the Committee, and Senator Borah, 79 Cong. Re. 1097-8, 
and it would seem that the explanation was that the 
stricken clause would actually discriminate against cooper¬ 
atives and prevent their being compensated for services 
rendered. This is, of course, in line with the statement 
by Asst. Secretary Davis, of the Department, set forth in 
our original brief at page 26. 

I. Plaintiffs’ Right to Sue: 

The citations on page 37 of Appellant’s brief appar¬ 
ently do not justify the claim there presented. It may be 
true that the intervenor cannot bring an entirely new 
issue into the case, although it has broad rights (Rector 
v. U. S., 20 F. 2nd, 845, 859). Here the Answer of the 
main defendant in par. 2 (Joint App. 4S) specifically 
brings into issue the right of the plaintiffs to maintain a 
class action and to act for the benefit of all other persons 
similarly situated. Therefore, the intervenor appellant’s 
first point in its brief is a proper one. It is well known 
that an intervenor can question—indeed, it is his duty to 
question—the real jurisdiction of the Court. (2 Moore’s 
Fed. Prac. y Sec. 2412, p. 2377). 

In this connection a clear issue was raised as to the 
maintenance of the action as a class one, and apparently 
the trial judge did not pass on this question in either his 
findings or conclusions. 

Not only was there a heavy preponderance of votes of 
non-cooperative producers in favor of the order, but also 
witness Carten, (Joint App. 240), as a non-cooperative pro¬ 
ducer, endorsed the cooperative provisions as payment 
for services to all producers. 

J. Provisions for Deductions in New York Statutes: 

The statement on page 30 of the Appellee’s brief as to 
the New York Statutes is erroneous. As stated in our 
original brief at pgs. 40 and 41, the 1937 Statute did pro- 





7 


vide for payments to co-operatives for marketing serv¬ 
ices. The wording was: 

“Any marketing agreement or order of the Commis¬ 
sioner may provide for necessary deductions from pay¬ 
ments to producers to provide for marketing services 
to them,...” Sec’t. 258-m. 

There was also the following clause in the declaration 
of policy (Sect. 258-k): 

“. . . that it is the policy of this state to promote, 
foster and encourage the intelligent and orderly mar¬ 
keting of milk through producer owned and controlled 
co-operative associations,.. .** 

Pursuant to the above, the provisions of New York Offi¬ 
cial Order 126 concurrent and identical in terms with Fed¬ 
eral Order No. 27 provided for deduction for payments 
to co-operatives. The terms of the Federal Order are set 
forth in footnote 14 in United States v. Rock Royal , 307 
U. S. 533, 551. Also pursuant to State legislation, the 
State issued Official Order 127 regulating handling of 
milk in the Niagara-Frontier Marketing Area (Buffalo) 
providing for payments to co-operatives, the qualifications 
therefore being in the same language as in Art. VII, Sec. 5, 
of Federal Order No. 27 and State Order 126. Both of 
these orders issued in 1938 were ratified and confirmed 
by the legislature in Sect. 3 of Chap. 760 of the laws of 
1939. Although there have been subsequent amendments 
as to the amount and basis of payments, these orders, at 
present including Federal Order No. 27, are in essence 
the same as the original. In addition. New York State 
Official Order 128, issued November 1939, relating to the 
Rochester Area, has incorporated the principles of the 
Buffalo Order. 

There was also in the original of these orders provisions 
for deductions to be made to pay operators of country re¬ 
ceiving stations, whether operated by dealers or co-opera¬ 
tives, for shipments of surplus milk to manufacturing 





8 


plants as a service to the industry. These services were 
separate and distinct from those for which co-operatives 
were paid. 

K. Other Orders Providing Deductions: 

While the Order No. 4 was not specific as to handling 
of surplus and supply of the market in times of shortage, 
it did provide as to five cent payments (§904.9 (a) (2)) 
that it should apply only to milk sold to handlers, and also 
providing in substance that it did not apply to sales in 
lower classes if such sales were not available as Class I 
to other handlers. 

The New York Order No. 27 has been more specific, and 
in §927.9 (f) provides as one of the conditions for pay¬ 
ments that a co-operative furnish milk in times of short 
supply to the marketing area and utilize milk in times of 
long supply in such manner as to secure the greatest pos¬ 
sible return to all producers. 

The statement on page 32 of the Appellee’s brief as 
only one instance of co-operative payments is erroneous. 
Page 28 of our original brief cited the provision in the 
Indiana law of 1935 and the license for the Twin Cities 
area under the Federal Act in August, 1933, and on page 
26 reference is made to the “check-off” in the Chicago 
area. There was also a provision in Order No. 3 dated 
January 30, 1936, affecting the St. Louis area (Sec. 5 of 
Art. IX), for an extra payment by a handler to co-opera¬ 
tive associations for services to such handlers. This order 
provided for a dealer blend instead of a market blend. 
This order was ratified in Sec. 4 of the 1937 Act. See 
House Report No. 468 March 24, 1939, p. 4. Thus there 
were instances of at least four “check-offs” to be consid¬ 
ered in connection with the section as to co-operative en¬ 
couragement, and also in connection with the statement of 
the Congressional Committees in substance that the provi- 


9 


sions of Sec. 8c of the Act embody the methods employed 
by the co-operative associations. See pages 25 and 26 
of original brief. 

Respectfully submitted, 

Seward A. Miller 
Frank B. Lent 
New York City 
Attorneys for Appellant, 
Dairymen's League Cooper¬ 
ative Association, Inc. 

Wm. E. Leahy 
Wm. J. Hughes, Jr. 

Bowen Building 
Washington, D. C. 

Of Counsel